Advertisement

Geographical Model of a Self-Organising Megalopolis with Time-Space Convergence

  • Isao Mizuno
Chapter
  • 287 Downloads
Part of the The GeoJournal Library book series (GEJL, volume 70)

Abstract

In industrialised countries, urban population and industrial production have been concentrated in some metropolitan areas, which have created a megalopolis from the expansion of their suburbs, where socio-economic functions of large cities are strongly linked with each other by high-speed transportation networks. For example, the United States megalopolis is well-known as a belt of large cities from Boston through New York to Washington D.C. on the Atlantic coast, and the Japanese megalopolis connects three metropolitan areas, Tokyo, Nagoya, and Osaka on the Pacific coast. Newly industrialised Asian countries or regions, such as South Korea, Taiwan, and Malaysia, are also developing megalopolis embryos or development belts. It can be generally stated that, as a national economy develops, one specific region becomes a megalopolis at the expense of the other regions. This phenomenon raises two questions. What economic processes differentiate the megalopolis from under-developed areas? Which geographical areas can selectively become a megalopolis? Two types of studies, the “more economic” and “more geographic” economic geographies (Lukermann, 1958), have tackled these questions in the location-theory literature.

Keywords

Urban Population Transportation Network Economic Geography Urban System Urban Agglomeration 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Abe, T. (1997), How has the `Back side of Japan“ been made? Nihon-Keizai-Hyoronsha, Tokyo. ( J)Google Scholar
  2. Allen, P.M. and M. Sanglier (1979), `A dynamic model of growth in a central place system.’ Geographical Analysis, 11, 256–272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Allen, P.M. and M. Sanglier (1981), `Urban evolution, self-organization, and decision-making.’ Environment and Planning A, 13, 169–183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arthur, W.B. (1994), Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.Google Scholar
  5. Barnes, T.J. (1996), Logics of Dislocation: Models, Metaphors, and Meanings of Economic Space. The Guilford Press, New York.Google Scholar
  6. Bura, S., F. Guerin-Pace, H. Mathian, D. Pumain and L. Sanders (1996), ‘Multiagent systems and the dynamics of a settlement system.’ Geographical Analysis, 28, 161–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Christaller, W. (1933), Die zentralen Orte in Suddeutschland. Fischer, Jena.Google Scholar
  8. Clarke, M. and A.G. Wilson (1983), `The dynamics of urban spatial structure: progress and problems.’ Journal of Regional Science, 23, 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Duranton, G. (1999), `Distance, land, and proximity: Economic analysis and the evolution of cities.’ Environment and Planning A, 31, 2169–2188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Ewers, H.J. (1995), `The locational impact of declining costs of transportation and communication.’ In H. Girsch (ed.), Urban Agglomeration and Economic Growth. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, pp. 183–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Fotheringham, A.S. (1981), `Spatial structure and distance-decay parameters.’ Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 71, 425–436.Google Scholar
  12. Fujita, M. (1989), Urban Economic Theory. Cambridge University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Fujita, M. and P. Krugman (1995), `When is the economy monocentric? Von Thunen and Chamberlin unified.’ Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25, 505–528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Fujita, M., P. Krugman and A.J. Venable (1999), The spatial economy: Cities, regions and international Trade. MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  15. Fujita, M. and H. Ogawa (1992), `Multiple equilibria and structural transition of non-monocentric urban configurations.’ Regional Science and Urban Economics, 12, 161–196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Furumaya, T. (1997), Back Side of Japan. Iwanami-Shoten, Tokyo. (J )Google Scholar
  17. Haggett, P., A.D. Cliff and A. Frey (1977), Locational Analysis in Human Geography. Arnold, London.Google Scholar
  18. Haken, H. (1978), Synergetic,: An Introduction, Nonequilibrium Phase Transitions and Self-Organization in Physics, Chemistry, and Biology. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
  19. Harris, C.D. (1954), `The market as a factor in the localization of industry in the US.’ Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 44, 311–348.Google Scholar
  20. Hoover, E.M. (1948), The Location of Economic Activity. McGraw-Hill: New York.Google Scholar
  21. Janelle, D.G. (1969), `Spatial reorganization: A model and concept.’ Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 59, 348–364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Junius, K. (1999), The Economic Geography of Production, Trade, and Development. Kieler Studien, Mohr Siebeck.Google Scholar
  23. Krugman, P. (1991a), Geography and Trade. MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  24. Krugman, P. (199 lb), `Increasing returns and economic geography.’ Journal of Political Economy, 99, 483–499.Google Scholar
  25. Krugman, P. (1993a), `On the number and locations of cities.’ European Economic Review, 37, 293–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Krugman, P. (1993b), `First nature, second nature, and metropolitan location.’ Journal of Regional Science, 33, 129–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Krugman, P. (1996), The Self-Organizing Economy. Blackwell, London.Google Scholar
  28. Lösch, A. (1940), Die räumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft. Gustav Fischer Verlag, Stuttgart. Lukermann, F. (1958), `Towards a more geographic economic geography.’ Professional Geographer, 10, 2–10.Google Scholar
  29. May, R. (1976), `Simple mathematical models with very complicated dynamics.’ Nature, 261, 459–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Mizuno, I. (1998), A Regional Disequilibrium Theory of Competitive and Cooperative Central Place Systems. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Geography, Tokyo Metropolitan University.Google Scholar
  31. Mori, T. (1997), `A modelling of megalopolis formation: The maturing of city systems.’ Journal of Urban Economics, 42, 133–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Morikawa, H. (1962), `Urban distribution in the early Meiji era, Japan.’ Jimbun-Chiri (The Human Geography), 14, 377–395. (JE)Google Scholar
  33. Myrdal, G. (1954), Economic Theory and the Under-Developed Regions. Gerald Duckworth, London.Google Scholar
  34. Nicolis, G. and 1. Prigogine (1977), Self-Organization in Non-Equilibrium Systems: From Dissipative Structures to Order through Fluctuations. Wiley Inter-Science, New York.Google Scholar
  35. Palander, T. (1935), Beitrage zur Standortstheorie. Akademisk Avhandling, Uppsala.Google Scholar
  36. Peeters, D., J.F. Thisse and 1. Thomas (1998), `Transportation networks and the location of human activity.’ Geographical Analysis, 30, 355–371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Plummer, P. (1999), `Capital accumulation, economic restructuring, and nonequilibrium regional growth dynamics.’ Geographical Analysis, 31, 267–287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Portugali, J. (2000), Self-Organization and the City. Springer, Berlin.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Pred, A. (1966), The Spatial Dynamics of U.S. Urban-Industrial Growth, 1800–1914: Interpretative and Theoretical Essays. MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  40. Prigogine, 1. and SI. tengers. (1984), Order out of Chaos. Bantam, New York.Google Scholar
  41. Ricci, L.A. (1999), `Economic geography and comparative advantage: Agglomeration versus specialization.’ European Economic Review, 43, 357–377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Simon, H. (1957), Models of Man. John Wiley Sons, New York.Google Scholar
  43. Smith, D.M. (1981), Industrial Location. John Wiley, New York.Google Scholar
  44. Uda, T. (ed.) (1995), The Development of Modern Japan and the Railroad History. Nihon-KeizaiHyoronsha, Tokyo. (J)Google Scholar
  45. Weber, A. (1909), ber den Standort der Industrien 1, Tubingen.Google Scholar
  46. White, R. and G. Engelen (1993), `Cellular automata and fractal urban form: A cellular modelling approach to the evolution of urban land use patterns.’ Environment and Planning A, 25, 1175–1199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Wong, D.W.S. and A.S. Fotheringham (1990), `Urban systems as examples of bounded chaos: Exploring the relationship between fractal dimension, rank-size, and rural-to-urban migration.’ Geografiska Annaler, 72B, 89–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Yamada, M. (1985), `Urban system in Japan.’ In T. Yamaguchi (ed.), Urban Systems in the World. Kokon-Shoin, Tokyo, pp. 1–39. (J)Google Scholar
  49. Yamamoto, H. (ed.) (1994), Historical Studies of the Modern Transportation Development. Hosei University Press, Tokyo. (J)Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2003

Authors and Affiliations

  • Isao Mizuno
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of GeographyOchanomizu UniversityOtsuka, Bunkyo-ku, TokyoJapan

Personalised recommendations