Skip to main content

Introductory Remarks

  • Chapter
  • 137 Accesses

Part of the book series: Economy & Environment ((ECEN,volume 19))

Abstract

Increasing economic integration of sovereign nations, reflected by the growth of trade flows in the past decades and associated with a rapid increase of economic activities and world-wide GDP, has also been accompanied by an alarming increase of local, national, international and global environmental problems. Economists tend to view this as a coincidence, treating the two developments as separate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See standard textbooks on international trade such as Gandolfo [1994] or Markusen et al. [1995].

    Google Scholar 

  2. See for example Baumol & Oates [1989] for a comprehensive textbook of environmental economics.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Esty [1994, 9pp] for a summary of environmentalists’ critique of free trade.

    Google Scholar 

  4. It should be noted that GATT/WTO rules and regulations do not prevent trade measures taken pursuant to environmental objective in general. However, trade measures addressing production and process methods of imported goods are not sanctioned by the GATT/WTO.

    Google Scholar 

  5. For an extensive summary of the debate see Esty [1994].

    Google Scholar 

  6. From a (neo-classical) point of view, environmental problems arising from human activities are subsumed under negative externalities or external effects; compare Rauscher [1997, 19pp] for further elaboration on environmental problems as externalities.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Compare Baumol & Oates [1988, 258], Feess [1998, 207], and Siebert [1995a, 170]. Examples are pollution of inland water resources, or smoke generated by a production process which is not transported outside the vicinity of its source.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Some authors further distinguish regional environmental problems, i.e. spill-over externalities which affect a subset of the world community. Siebert [1995a, 187pp] and Feess [1998, 210pp] for example analytically differentiate regional and global externalities.

    Google Scholar 

  9. This reflects the legal definition. However, the definition used in non-legal literature for global environmental commons also encompasses resources whose value affects nations other than those having jurisdiction over them, i.e. portions of the globe located within the jurisdiction of sovereign states whose value accrues to all mankind (e.g. bio-diversity); compare Tschofen [1992, 1/2].

    Google Scholar 

  10. Global environmental commons comprise common pool resources such as minerals in deep sea beds, common sink resources such as the atmosphere and the oceans, and global public goods such as bio-diversity and the ozone layer. This tripartite nature of global environmental commons has been stressed by Siebert [1990, 1]. Yet other definitions only distinguish two aspects, i.e. common pool and sink resources (e.g. Eckhaus [1993, 3] and Vogler [1995, 3]), or subsume all global environmental commons under global public goods (e.g. Oberthur [1992, 11]).

    Google Scholar 

  11. The term ‘tragedy of the commons’ has been introduced by Hardin [1968] with respect to population growth. However, it is now commonly used with reference to global environmental resources.

    Google Scholar 

  12. The problems of ozone depletion and global warming are summarised in chapter 13.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Blackhurst & Subramanian [1992, 248] and Sandler [1992].

    Google Scholar 

  14. E.g. Merrifield [1988] and Choi & Johnson [1992]. A combination of both, i.e. an externality which harms society directly and indirectly has also been considered (see Pethig [1992] and Rauscher [1997, ch.5]).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Similar formulations have been used by Hoel [1993] and Rauscher [1991a&b, 1994, 1995d & 1997 ch.5].

    Google Scholar 

  16. This assumption is analytically convenient; it avoids environmental quality affecting the structure of demand. A further implication of additive separability is that both welfare components are superior. Hence, if consumption utility increases — e.g. as a consequence of trade liberalisation — society’s desire for environmental quality grows as well. (For a detailed discussion of additively separable utility functions see Deaton & Muellbauer [1980, ch.5]. For the superiority feature in particular, see Deaton & Muellbauer [1980, 139]).The separability assumption is made in the majority of models similar to ours. However, some authors choose a less restrictive approach (e.g. Copeland [1993 & 1994], v. Long & Siebert [1989], Ludema & Wooton [1994], Markusen [1975] Panagariya et al. [1993], Pethig [1976], and Siebert [1977]).

    Google Scholar 

  17. As regards the source of pollution, it is also possible to model externalities arising from consumption (e.g. Rauscher [1997, ch.5] and Beghin et al. [1994b & 1996]. However, for our purposes — i.e. addressing environmental policy and trade policy linkages — a PPM externality is more appropriate since multilateral trade rules ban trade instruments addressing PPM externalities, while trade instruments addressing consumption externalities are allowed. Chakarian [1994], Lee [1994], Tudini [1993], and Vaughan [1994] provide a survey of PPM pollution in the context of trade and environment.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Further specifications of environmental pollution, i.e. which environmental medium is affected and their dynamic features, i.e. whether the damaging effect arises from the stock or the flow of a pollutant, are neglected in our study. For a taxonomy of environmental pollution see Siebert [1995a, 21/22].

    Google Scholar 

  19. Choi & Johnson [1992], Markusen [1975], and McGuire [1982] for example use Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson type models with sector-specific environmental externalities. In Ricardo-Viner models Copeland [1993] and Rauscher [1991b] also use a sector-specific environmental externality arising as a by-product of production in one of two sectors. Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson models in which both sectors release environmentally harmful emissions are modelled by Pethig [1976] and Siebert [1977&1979]. n-sector international trade general equilibrium models where all sectors pollute the environment are considered by Copeland [1994] and Hœl [1993].

    Google Scholar 

  20. Yet, if this model was to be generalised to a Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson formulation, factor specificity would imply that both sectors pollute the environment as it does in Klepper [1994], Pethig [1976] and Siebert [1977&’79]. Panagariya et al. [1993] set our a similar model by augmenting an Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model with a third, sector-specific input factor which causes an environmental externality.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Often environmental pollution arises in capital-intensive sectors (e.g. industrial sectors, energy generation) where they are largely determined by the production technology, which in turn reflects the particular capital stock available in the economy; compare Sohmen [1976, 228]. Furthermore, a number of pollutants (e.g. sulphur dioxide and carbon dioxide) are positively correlated with the capital stock of economies; see World Bank [1992, 11]. Further advantages of our modelling approach are that the model can be handled like a ‘normal’ Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model; i.e. the environmental externality does not add analytical complexity. At the same time, we do not reduce the generality of the Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson approach.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Focussing on the relation between the environment and trade as they appear in our model, we suppress many aspects feeding the ‘awkwardness’ (Rauscher [1997, 1]) of the connection. For example, we neglect environmental cost from transportation (see Helm [1995, 29pp]) and problems associated with cross-border waste disposal (see Rauscher [1997, ch.4]. A further dimension, namely the ‘clash of cultures’ (Esty [1994, ch.2]) between environmentalists and free-traders as protagonists in the debate is completely ignored in our study.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Compare also Helm [1995, 34pp] and Rauscher [1997, 1].

    Google Scholar 

  24. Hence, if an increase in environmental protection efforts stemming from the latter effect trigger environmentally less disruptive PPMs, the aggregate effect cannot be determined in advance. Furthermore, since the Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model is static, empirical observations cannot be expected to reflect its predictions; see Helm [1995, 32pp] for a cursory empirical glance.

    Google Scholar 

  25. The validity of the gains of trade theorem (see Gandolfo [1994, 54pp] and Markusen et al. [1995, 61pp]) is based on a number of assumptions of which the absence of market failures such as (uninternalised) environmental externalities is just one.

    Google Scholar 

  26. This categorisation follows Rauscher [1997, 21]. Siebert [1995a, 125/126] lists in addition moral suasion, publicly financed pollution abatement and abatement subsidies. The three we have listed yield an identical allocation in a static competitive economy where welfare-maximising governments have perfect information.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Government allocates (optimal) pollution quotas or restricts technology choice of firms by setting PPM standards (if pollution is generated by PPMs).

    Google Scholar 

  28. To be an efficient instrument, this tax should be levied on emissions; its optimal level corresponds to the Pigouvian tax, i.e. is set equal to marginal social damage caused by the negative environmental externality.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Government determines the (optimal) emission level and distributes (or auctions) pollution permits accordingly. To yield an efficient solution, a perfect market for these permits is needed.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Rauscher [1991a, 1995c&d] also uses taxes as regulatory instrument. We do not perform a 30 comparison of alternative environmental policy instruments which has been frequently undertaken for closed (Bohm & Russel [1985] provide a survey) and also open (Verdier [1993], Rauscher [1992a]) economies.

    Google Scholar 

  31. E.g. Bhagwati & Srinivasan [1971], Hazari [1978], Herberg & Kemp [1971], Jones [1971], and Magee [1971, 1973&1976].

    Google Scholar 

  32. In general, tariffs can be positive or negative; negative tariffs correspond to an export subsidy. In our theoretical investigation, we shall restrict tariffs to positive tariffs.

    Google Scholar 

  33. E.g. voluntary export restraints, local content requirements, administrative requirements and product standards (compare Krugman & Obstfeld [1997, 197] and Siebert [1994, 179]).

    Google Scholar 

  34. Reasons for restricting our investigation to tariffs are twofold: tariffs and quantity restrictions are in the absence of uncertainty equivalent (see Vousden [1990, ch.2]). Furthermore, since we chose a tax rather than tradable permits as environmental policy instrument, we chose tariffs as environmental policy instrument as the corresponding (price) instrument in trade policy.

    Google Scholar 

  35. It is also possible to analyse trade instruments as (sole) environmental policy instruments (as done by Brandner & Taylor [1998]). However, we confine ourselves to the case when environmental policy is used for trade policy objectives. In view of increasing environmental regulation and decreasing scope for trade policy, we think that this case is more realistic.

    Google Scholar 

  36. The term ‘regulatory capture’ is borrowed from Stigler; similarly adequate would be the term ‘political capture’.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Compare Deardorff [1994].

    Google Scholar 

  38. While the assumption that producers of a particular good gain regulatory capture is rather ad hoc, the fact that producers (rather than consumers) are successful in manipulating government is not: since there are generally fewer producers than consumers, gains from rent seeking are larger for the former. Furthermore, members of a particular industry are often already organised which alleviates coordination for lobbying activities (compare Vousden [1990, ch.8].

    Google Scholar 

  39. For a detailed treatment of the comparative statics approach see Krauss & Johnson [1974].

    Google Scholar 

  40. I.e. a Pareto optimum, an idea originally developed by Pareto [1909]; compare Debreu [1983, ch.1] and Lockwood [1987] on the concept of Pareto optimality in economics.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See Gandolfo [1994, 57], and Markusen et al. [1995, 67p]. For this result, we also need the assumption that government intervention does not take place in these perfectly competitive economies.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Such is for example the case if an environmental externality is present, and prices resulting from decentralised, uncoordinated actions no longer accurately reflect environmental (and hence economic) scarcities. See Mas-Colell et al. [1995, ch. 11] for externalities in general and Baumol & Oates [1988] for environmental ones in particular.

    Google Scholar 

  43. When for example an environmental externality is present, the Coase Theorem applies: if those suffering from the externality and those causing it can (costlessly) bargain, a welfare optimum is restored; see Coase [I960]. Alternative to the bargaining solution, a welfare-maximising government can also correct the market failure with the equivalent result if an efficient policy instrument is chosen, see above.

    Google Scholar 

  44. The parallel to market imperfections causing inefficient resources allocation within an economy is obvious: although none of the assumptions required for a competitive equilibrium in each individual economy is violated, the world market exhibits imperfections, i.e. market power by one of the market participants.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See Markusen et al. [1995, 258].

    Google Scholar 

  46. Optimal domestic environmental policy does not restore global optimality since it does not internalise cross-border externalities. However, a supranational government — for whose establishment countries have to cooperate — can introduce global environmental policy measures to yield a Pareto optimum. Alternatively, governments can bargain to find a Coase solution.

    Google Scholar 

  47. For an introduction to game theory see Rasmusen [1989]; for a sophisticated treatment of the issues see Fudenberg & Tirole [1991]. For the game theory used in our study a basic knowledge of the concepts as presented in Tirole [1988, ch.11] suffices. The Nash equilibrium concept was originally developed by Nash [1950&51] (compare Tirole [1988, 427]). If countries decide sequentially upon their policy measures, the relevant concept would be a Stackelberg equilibrium (originally developed by Stackelberg [1934]; compare Tirole [1988,315]).

    Google Scholar 

  48. See for example Ranné [1996, 1]: “In den Medien oder in der politischen Diskussion werden Handelspartner üblicherweise des Öko-dumpings bezeichnet, wenn ihre Umweltschutzvorschriften weniger streng sind als ein bestimmtes Referenzniveau. Dieses Referenzniveau kann sich .... an den in anderen Ländern üblichen Reglementierungen [oder einem weltweiten Standard] orientieren...Meist werden jedoch als Meßlatte die Umweltschutzvorschriften des eigenen Landes angelegt.”

    Google Scholar 

  49. The relation between eco-dumping and ‘normal’ dumping which refers to locally differentiated prices may not be immediately obvious. First of all, ‘normal’ dumping is undertaken by individual producers, while for eco-dumping governments are the relevant agents. Moreover, while ‘normal’ dumping refers to a situation when exported goods are sold at a price below the one prevailing at the domestic market, eco-dumping may be undertaken by import-competing countries as well. The parallel between them is the fact that ‘normal’ dumping may occur when governments grant subsidies to domestic firms; eco-dumping is thus seen as an ‘implicit’ subsidy (Ranné [1996, 3]; for a different view according to which eco-dumping has nothing to do with ‘normal’ dumping see Kuhn & Tivig [1996, 7]).

    Google Scholar 

  50. This corresponds to a definition advanced by Revesz [1994, 376–9]. Similarly Rauscher’s [1993a, 5] definition: “... environmental dumping is pricing of environmental resources, that are used in the production of export goods, at less than marginal domestic social cost”, which we augment by the fact that lax policies are introduced because of trade relations. Rauscher [1994, 825] advances and investigates a third definition of eco-dumping, namely the laxer treatment of an exportables sector with regard to environmental regulation.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See Revesz [1994, 373] and Rauscher [1997, 279/280]. Often, the term used in this context is ‘environmental race to the bottom’, which might be interpreted to imply no regulation at all. This concept is not particularly useful, since strategic interaction resulting in too low levels everywhere does not depend on the level actually going all the way to zero (see Wilson [1996, 393, footnote 1]). Esty [1994] uses the term ‘political dra’ in similar circumstances.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See e.g. VanGrasstek [1992, 233]. The term is also used by Rauscher [1997] to describe situations when governments introduce too stringent environmental regulation.

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Wilson [1996, 395].

    Google Scholar 

  54. Whether it does is in fact one of the central questions addressed in this study.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2000 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kraus, C. (2000). Introductory Remarks. In: Import Tariffs as Environmental Policy Instruments. Economy & Environment, vol 19. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-9614-5_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-9614-5_1

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-90-481-5461-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-015-9614-5

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics