Advertisement

Solidarity pp 243-272 | Cite as

Solidarity as a Social Norm and as a Constitutional Norm

  • Michael Baurmann
Part of the Philosophical Studies in Contemporary Culture book series (PSCC, volume 5)

Abstract

I will use the term “solidarity” in a broad sense. By acting in solidarity I mean the voluntary transfer of goods or services to another individual or to a group of individuals whenever this transfer is not the object of an explicit contract. A transfer of this kind is unconditional in the sense that it is not contingent on the enforceable duty of the beneficiary to provide a specified equivalent for the gains he or she obtains. Acting in solidarity with a single individual means to contribute voluntarily and unconditionally to an individual good. Acting in solidarity with a group of individuals means to contribute voluntarily and unconditionally to a public good.1 If we analyze the empirical conditions which promote or impede solidarity in the sense of voluntarily and unconditionally contributing to individual or public goods we can identify three main empirical constellations. Let us begin with the constellations in regard to solidarity in favor of public goods.

Keywords

Public Good Individual Contribution Individual Good Moral Norm Individual Interest 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. Alexander, R. D.: 1987, The Biology of Moral Systems,New York.Google Scholar
  2. Axelrod, R.: 1981, `The emergence of cooperation among egoists’, American Political Science Review 75, 306–318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Axelrod, R.: 1984, The Evolution of Cooperation, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
  4. Axelrod, R.: 1986, `An evolutionary approach to norms’, American Political Science Review 80, 1095–1111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Baker, G. P., Jensen M. C. and Murphy, K. J.: 1988, `Compensation and incentives: practice versus theory’, Journal of Finance 43, 593–616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Baurmann, M. 1993, `Rechte und Normen als soziale Tatsachen. Zu James S. Colemans Grundlegung der Sozialtheorie’, Analyse und Kritik 15, 36–61.Google Scholar
  7. Baurmann, M.: 1996a, Der Markt der Tugend. Recht und Moral in der liberalen Gesellschaft, Mohr, Tübingen.Google Scholar
  8. Baurmann, M.: 1996b, `Kann Homo oeconomicus tugendhaft sein?’, Homo oeconomicus 13, 1–24.Google Scholar
  9. Baurmann, M.: 1996c, `Universalisierung und Partikularisierung der Moral. Ein individualistisches Erklärungsmodell’, in R. Hegselmann and H. Kliemt (eds.), Moral und Interesse, München. [in print]Google Scholar
  10. Baurmann, M., and Kliemt, H.: 1995, `Zur Ökonomie der Tugend’, in: P. Weise (ed.), Ökonomie und Gesellschaft, Jahrbuch 11, pp. 13–44.Google Scholar
  11. Binmore, K.: 1992, Fun and Games. A Text on Game Theory, Heath, Lexington-Toronto, Mass.Google Scholar
  12. Brennan, G., and Lomasky, L.: 1993, Democracy and Decision. The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Buchanan, J. M.: 1977, `Ethics, expected values, and large numbers’, in Freedom in Constitutional Contract, Texas A and M University Press, College Station, pp. 151–168.Google Scholar
  14. Coleman, J. S.: 1990, Foundations of Social Theory,Belknap Press, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
  15. Diekmann, A., and Mitter, P. (eds.): 1986, Paradoxical Effects of Social Behaviour,Physica,Heidelberg.Google Scholar
  16. Downs, A.: 1957, An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper, New York.Google Scholar
  17. Frank, R. H.: 1988, Passions Within Reason. The Strategic Role of the Emotions, Norton, New York.Google Scholar
  18. Frey, B. S.: 1992. S.: 1992, ‘Tertium datur: Pricing, Regulating and Intrinsic Motivation’, Kyklos 45, 16 1184.Google Scholar
  19. Frey, B. S.: 1993a, `Motivation as a limit to pricing’, Journal of Economic Psychology 14, 635664.Google Scholar
  20. Frey, B. S.: 1993b, `Shirking or work morale?’, European Economic Review 37, 1523–1532. Frey, B. S., and Bohnet, I.: 1994, `Die Ökonomie zwischen extrinsischer und intrinsischer Motivation’, Homo oeconomicus 11,1–19.Google Scholar
  21. Gauthier, D.: 1986, Morals by Agreement, Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  22. Gouldner, A. W.: 1961, `The norm of reciprocity’, American Sociological Review 25, 161–189. Granovetter, M.: 1985, `Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness’, American Journal of Sociology 85, 481–510.Google Scholar
  23. Giith, W. and Kliemt, H.: 1993, `Menschliche Kooperation basierend auf Vorleistungen und Vertrauen’, in Jahrbuch für Politische Ökonomie 12, pp. 145–173.Google Scholar
  24. Güth, W. and Kliemt, H.: 1994, `Competition or co-operation: on the evolutionary economics of trust, exploitation and moral attitudes’, Metroeconomica 45, 155–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Hardin, R.: 1971, `Collective action as an agreeable n-prisoners’ dilemma’, Behavioral Science, 472–481.Google Scholar
  26. Hardin, R.: 1982, Collective Action, Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore.Google Scholar
  27. Hart, H. L. A.: 1961, The Concept of Law, Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
  28. Hegselmann, R • 1996, Was könnte dazu motivieren, moralisch zu sein? Überlegungen zum Verhältnis von Moralität und Klugheit’, R. Hegselmann and H. Kliemt (eds.), Moral und Interesse, München. [in print]Google Scholar
  29. Hegselmann, R., Raub, W. and Voss, T.: 1986, `Zur Entstehung der Moral aus natürlichenGoogle Scholar
  30. Neigungen. Eine spieltheoretische Spekulation’, Analyse und Kritik 8, 150–177. Hirsch, F.: 1976, Social Limits to Growth,Harvard University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  31. Hirshleifer, J.: 1987, `On the emotions as guarantors of threats and premises’, in J. Dupré (ed.),The Latest on the Best: Essays in Evolution and Optimality, MIT Press, Cambridge, pp. 307–326.Google Scholar
  32. Hoerster, N.: 1986, `Kritischer Vergleich der Theorien der Rechtsgeltung von Hans Kelsen und H. L. A. Hart’, in S. L. Paulson and R. Walter (eds.), Untersuchungen zur Reinen Rechtslehre, Manz, Wien, pp. 1–19.Google Scholar
  33. Hoerster, N.: 1989, `Norm’, in: Handlexikon zur Wissenschaftstheorie, H. Seifert and G. Radnitzky (ed.), Ehrenwirth, Munchen, p. 272.Google Scholar
  34. Hondrich, K.-O., and Koch-Arzberger, C.: 1992, Solidarität in der modernen Gesellschaft, Fischer, Frankfurt/Main.Google Scholar
  35. Jasay, A. de: 1989, Social Contract, Free Ride. A Study of the Public Goods Problem, Clarendon Press, Oxford, England.Google Scholar
  36. Kliemt, H.: 1986, Antagonistische Kooperation. Elementare spieltheoretische Modelle spontaner Ordnungsentstehung, Alber, Freiburg, München.Google Scholar
  37. Kliemt, H.: 1988, `Thomas Hobbes, David Hume und die Bedingungen der Möglichkeit eines Staates’, in Akten des 12. Internationalen Wittgenstein Symposiums, Wien, pp. 152–160.Google Scholar
  38. Kliemt, H.: 1993, `Constitutional commitments’, in P. Herder-Domeich. (eds.), Jahrbuch für Politische Ökonomie 12, pp. 145–173.Google Scholar
  39. Luce, D. R., and Raiffa, H.: 1957, Games and Decisions, Wiley, New York.Google Scholar
  40. Maclntyre, A.: 1984, Is Patriotism a Virtue?, The Lindley Lecture, University of Kansas. Mueller, D. C.: 1986, `Rational egoism versus adaptive egoism as fundamental postulate for a descriptive theory of human behavior’, Public Choice 44, 3–23.Google Scholar
  41. Mueller, D. C.: 1992, `On the foundations of social science research’, Analyse und Kritik 14, 195–220.Google Scholar
  42. North, D. C.: 1981, Structure and Change in Economic History, Norton, New York.Google Scholar
  43. Olson, M.: 1965, The Logic of Collective Action. Public Goods and the Theory of Groups, Harvard, Cambridge.Google Scholar
  44. Rapoport, A. and Chammah, A. M.: 1965, Prisoner’s Dilemma, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.Google Scholar
  45. Samuelson, P. A.: 1954, `The pure theory of public expenditures’, Review of Economics and Statistics 36, 387–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Scott, J. F.: 1971, Internalization of Norms. A Sociological Theory of Moral Commitment, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs.Google Scholar
  47. Trivers, R.: 1971, `The evolution of reciprocal altruism’, The Quarterly Review of Biology, 3551.Google Scholar
  48. Trivers, R.: 1985, Social Evolution, Benjamin/Cummings Pub. Co., Menlo Park. Ullmann-Margalit, E.: 1977, The Emergence of Norms, Clarendon Press, Oxford, England. Vanberg, V.: 1975, Die zwei Soziologien. Individualismus und Kollektivismus in der Sozialtheorie, Mohr, Tübingen.Google Scholar
  49. Vanberg, V.: 1982, Markt und Organisation. Individualistische Sozialtheorie und das Problem korporativen Handelns, Mohr, Tübingen.Google Scholar
  50. Vanberg, V.: 1987, Morality and Economics. De Moribus Est Disputandum, Transaction Books, New Brunswick.Google Scholar
  51. Vanberg, V.: 1988, `Rules and choice in economics and sociology’, in Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie 7, pp. 146–167.Google Scholar
  52. Vanberg, V.: 1993, `Rational choice, rule-following and institution. an evolutionary perspective’, in U. Mäki. (eds.), Rationality, Institutions and Economic Methodology, Rout-ledge, London and New York, pp. 171–200.Google Scholar
  53. Vanberg, V. and Buchanan, J. M.: 1988, `Rational choice and moral order’, Analyse und Kritik 10, 138–160.Google Scholar
  54. Vanberg, V. and Congleton, R. D.: 1992, `Rationality, morality, and exit’, American Political Science Review 86, 418–431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Voss, T.: 1985, Rationale Akteure und soziale Institutionen, Oldenbourg, München. Weber, M.: 1922, Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, reprint 1972, Mohr, Tübingen.Google Scholar
  56. Weede, E.: 1990, Wirtschaft, Staat und Gesellschaft. Zur Soziologie der kapitalistischen Marktwirtschaft und der Demokratie, Mohr, Tübingen.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 1999

Authors and Affiliations

  • Michael Baurmann
    • 1
  1. 1.University of DüsseldorfGermany

Personalised recommendations