Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Theory and Decision Library ((TDLB,volume 15))

  • 217 Accesses

Abstract

A decisive stimulus to the development of formal decision theory was provided by the formulation of the principle of expected gain. We have seen how this principle was used to settle the question of how the stakes of an interrupted gambling game were to be divided. The term ‘moral expectation’ given to the principle at the time reflected a normative interpretation of expected gain: what the player could ‘justly’ expect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 259.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Parish records show that William Shakespear was baptized on April 26, 1564. April 23 is commonly surmised to be the date of his birth. The exact date is unknown. To continue with this bizarre but instructive example of a misconception about the meaning of probability, recall that in the Julian calendar April was the second month (hence September, October, etc. were seventh, eighth, etc.). If we write Shakespear’s birthdate 23.2 or 2.23 and interpret the period as a sign for multiplication, we again get 46! How much more ‘evidence’ is required to endow this number with some mystical property somehow connected with Shakespear?

    Google Scholar 

  2. The expression on the right side of (5.12) is derived from the normalizing condition. Let x/a = y. Then dy=(1/a)dx. f f 0, (1/a) f(x/a)dx= f °°, f (y)dy = 1, as required.

    Google Scholar 

  3. A function that maps a function on a scalar is called a functional. The integrand of a definite integral is a function; the value of the integral is a scalar. Thus, a definite integral is a functional. ° The entropy of a density is a measure of the uncertainty associated with the random variable it represents. A density function concentrated around a particular value has low entropy. A density representing a uniform distribution has maximum entropy. It represents maximum ignorance about the value that a random variable will assume.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1989 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Rapoport, A. (1989). Subjective Aspects of Risk. In: Decision Theory and Decision Behaviour. Theory and Decision Library, vol 15. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-7840-0_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-015-7840-0_6

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-90-481-4047-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-015-7840-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics