Skip to main content

Science Policy Options and Priorities

  • Chapter
Science and Technology Policy
  • 46 Accesses

Abstract

In its widest application science policy is concerned with education, the stock of knowledge, its availability and use, and research and development. Technology policy is concerned with the adoption and use of techniques — innovation, diffusion of techniques and their replacement. As is indicated in Table 2.1, however, the borderline between the two policy types is not clearcut.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes and references

  1. Carter, C. F. and Williams, B. R. (1964), Government scientific policy and the growth of the British economy, The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 32,p.198.

    Google Scholar 

  2. As far as I am aware there have been no empirical studies of the extent to which different educational institutions in fact lag or lead in the use of techniques.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See, for instance, Iinuma, J. (1973), The introduction of American and European agricultural science into Japan in the Meiji era, in: Technical Change in Asian Agriculture (ed. R. T. Shand ), Australian National University Press, Canberra, pp. 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Oshima, K. (1973), Research and development and economic growth in Japan, in: Science and Technology in Economic Growth (ed. B. R. Williams ), Macmillan, London, p. 318.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Oshima, K. (see ref. 4) p. 323.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Carter, C. F. and Williams, B. R. (see ref. 1 ) p. 197.

    Google Scholar 

  7. See, for instance, Griliches, Z. (1958), Research costs and social returns: hybrid corn and related innovations, The Journal of Political Economy, 66, pp. 419–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Ben-Porath, Y. (1972), Some implications of economic size and level for investment in R and D, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 21, pp. 96–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Ben-Porath, Y. (see ref. 8). p. 98.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Carter, C. F. and Williams, B. R., (see ref. 1 ) p. 199.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Eads, G. and Nelson, R. R. (1971), Governmental support of advanced civilian technology: power reactors and supersonic transport, Public Policy, 19, pp. 405–427 (extract: p. 426).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Oshima, K. (see ref. 4) p. 320.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See, for example:

    Google Scholar 

  14. Kemp, M. C. (1955), Technological change, the terms of trade and welfare, The Economic Journal, 65, pp. 457–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Duncan, R. C. and Tisdell, C. A. (1971), Research and technical progress — the returns to the producers, The Economic Record, 47, pp. 124–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Bhagwati, J. (1958), Immiserizing growth: a geometrical note, Review of Economic Studies (June).

    Google Scholar 

  17. See discussion later of Japanese policy in this regard.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Contributors to the new technology theory of international trade include:

    Google Scholar 

  19. Posner, M. V. (1961), International trade and technical change, Oxford Economic Papers, 13, pp. 323–41.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Freeman, C. (1963), The plastics industry: a comparative study of research and innovation, National Institute Economic Review, (Nov.), pp. 22–62.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Hirsch, S. (1972), The United States electronics industry in international trade, text in: The Product Life Cycle and International Trade (ed. L. T. Wells Jr.), Harvard University, Boston, pp. 39–52.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Hufbauer, G. C. (1966), Synthetic Materials and the Theory of International Trade, Duckworth, London.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Wells, G. C. (1969), Test ofa product cycle model of international trade: U.S. exports of consumer durables, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83, pp. 152–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Gruber, W., Mehta, D. and Vernon, R. (1967), The R and D factor in international trade and international investment of United States industries, Journal of Political Economy, 75, pp. 20–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Lowinger, T. (1975), The technology factor and the export performance of U.S. manufacturing industries, Economic Enquiry, 13, pp. 221–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Teubal, M. (1975), Toward a neotechnology theory of comparative costs,Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89, pp. 414–31.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Gruber, W., Mehta, D. and Vernon, R. (see ref. 15f ) pp. 20–21.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Vernon, R. (1966), International investment and international trade in the product cycle, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, pp. 190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Baldwin, W. and Childs, G. L. (1969–70), The fast second and rivalry in research and development, Southern Economic Journal, 36, pp. 18–24.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Baldwin, W. and Childs, G. L. (see ref. 18 ) p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  31. If a new product is rapidly imitated by others and if they have advantages such as cost or marketing advantages, the innovator may gain little or even lose while the imitators profit handsomely.

    Google Scholar 

  32. This is a similar theory to the one advanced by Marris in his discussion of the rate ofgrowth of the firm and its profitability. See Marris, R. L. (1964), The Economic Theory of `Managerial’ Capitalism, Macmillan, London; and Wildsmith, J. R. (1973), Managerial Theories of the Firm, Martin Robertson, London, Ch. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  33. R and D expenditure may be partly a function of an economy’s growth rate and with a lag may feed back to increase that growth rate. This is particularly likely for industrial R and D since many firms devote a relatively fixed percentage, e.g. 2%, of their sales revenue to R and D.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Sec, for instance:

    Google Scholar 

  35. McConnell, C. R. and Peterson, W. C. (1965), Research and development: some evidence for small firms, Southern Economic Journal, 31, pp. 356–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Vernon, J. M. and Gusen, P. (1974), Technical change and firm size: The Pharmaceutical industry, Review of Economics and Statistics, 56, pp. 294–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Rosenberg, J. B. (1976), Research and market share: a reappraisal of the Schumpeter hypothesis, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 25, pp. 101–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Kamien, M. I. and Schwartz, N. L. (1975), Market structure and innovation: a survey, Journal of Economic Literature, 8, pp. 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Carter, C. F. and Williams, B. R. (see ref. 1.).

    Google Scholar 

  40. Baldwin, W. and Childs, G. L. (see ref. 18).

    Google Scholar 

  41. One of the problems with this presentation is that ideas are not homogeneous. However, the presentation is of heuristic value.

    Google Scholar 

  42. In other words scientific activity at home and home-produced ideas complement rather than compete with the import of ideas up to a point.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Up to a point the quantity of imported ideas may complement the quantity of ideas produced at home.

    Google Scholar 

  44. The efficient set is the set for which it is impossible to increase the quantity of imported ideas without reducing the quantity produced at home, and vice versa.

    Google Scholar 

  45. These curves are similar to iso-revenue curves or indifference curves in economic analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  46. For review of some of the relevant economic literature see:

    Google Scholar 

  47. Pearce, D. W. (1976), Environmental Economics, Longman, London.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Tisdell, C. (1978), A further review of pollution control, Research Report or Occasional Paper No. 44, Department of Economics, University of Newcastle, June.

    Google Scholar 

  49. This is ‘second best’ because unfavourable externalities may continue to exist and this may not be the most efficient way of reducing the overspills.

    Google Scholar 

  50. See, for instance, Kahn, A. E. (1966), The tyranny of small decisions: market failures, imperfections and the limits of economies, Kyklos, 19, pp. 23–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Recent Japanese science policy has been greatly influenced by this consideration. See Tisdell, C. (1975), An Australian review of Japanese science and energy policy, The Australian Quarterly, 47, pp. 44–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. For example, see Nordhaus, W. and Tobin, J. (1970), Is Growth Obsolete? Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 319, December, Yale University, New Haven.

    Google Scholar 

  53. For a discussion of these issues, see Mansfield, E. (1968), Defence, Science, and Public Policy,Norton, New York, Parts 2 and 3.

    Google Scholar 

  54. For an interesting study of spin-off and interaction in research, see Langrish, J., Gibbons, M., Evans, W. G., and Jevons, F. R. (1972), Wealth from Knowledge, Macmillan, London, especially pp. 24–32.

    Google Scholar 

  55. These arguments are summarized in Pavitt, K. (1976), Government support for industrial research and development in France: theory and practice, Minerva, 14, pp. 331–54.

    Google Scholar 

  56. The boundary lines are the ridge lines of production functions. See, for example:

    Google Scholar 

  57. Leftwich, R. H. (1976), The Price System and Resource Allocation, 6th edn, Dryden Press, Hinsdale, Ch. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Tisdell, C. (1972), Microeconomics: The Theory of Economic Allocation, John Wiley, Sydney, p. 143.

    Google Scholar 

  59. In production theory such combinations correspond to the use of more resources than are needed to produce the quantity of output achieved.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Toulmin, S. (1965), The complexity of scientific choice II: Culture, overheads or tertiary industry? Minerva, 4, p. 158.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Toulmin, S. (see ref. 42) p. 159.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Johnson, H. G. (1965), Federal support of basic research: some economic issues, in: Basic Research and National Goals, US Government Printing Office, Washington, p. 132.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Toulmin, S. (see ref. 42).

    Google Scholar 

  64. See Saunders, C. T. (1977), Concentration and specialization in Western industrial countries in: Industrial Policies and Technology Transfers between East and West (ed. C. T. Saunders), Springer Verlag, Vienna.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Scherer, F. M. (1965), Government research and development programs, in: Measuring Benefits of Government Investments (ed. R. Dorfman ), Brookings Institution, Washington, and comments by E. Mansfield in the same volume.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Johnson, H. G. (1975), Technology and Economic Interdependence, Macmillan, London, pp. 26–27.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See, for instance, Tisdell, C. (1977), The government, education and research as factors in the development of Newcastle and the Hunter, in: The Future Economic Prospects for Newcastle in its Region (ed. J. Hill ), Institute of Industrial Economics, University of Newcastle, pp. 123–42.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Japan is planning a science city away from Tokyo.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Johnson, P. (1973), Co-operative Research in Industry: An Economic Study, Martin Robertson, London.

    Google Scholar 

  70. Johnson, P. (see ref. 51).

    Google Scholar 

  71. King, A. (1974), Science and Policy: The International Stimulus, Oxford University Press, Oxford, p. 81

    Google Scholar 

  72. King, A. (see ref. 53). p. 82.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Boxer, A. H. (1969), Experts in Asia,Australian National University Press, Canberra, p. 31 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  74. See, for instance, Frank, A. G. (1971), Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America,Pelican, Harmondsworth, and other references given in Ch. 1, note 42.

    Google Scholar 

  75. For a stimulating discussion of appropriate technologies for LDCs see Schumacher, E. F. (1973), Small is Beautiful: Economics As If People Mattered, Harper and Row, New York; and by the same author, The Age of Plenty: A Christian View, St. Andrew Press, Edinburgh, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  76. See for example, Mandel, Ernst (1975), Late Capitalism, NLB, London.

    Google Scholar 

  77. The World Bank (1980), World Development Report 1980, Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 112–13.

    Google Scholar 

  78. For instance Helen Hughes and colleagues argue that official exchange rates compared to purchasing parity exchange rates result in official estimates of growth rates of income in LDCs being understated relative to those of industrialized countries. See

    Google Scholar 

  79. Hughes, Helen (1980), Achievements and objectives of industrialization, in: Policiesfor Industrial Progress in Developing Countries (edsJ. Cody, H. Hughes and D. Wall), Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  80. Hughes, Helen (1980), Australian international economic perspectives, ANZAAS Paper, May, World Bank (mimeo).

    Google Scholar 

  81. For background references on Lindblom’s thesis see Ch. 1, note 23.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1981 C. A. Tisdell

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tisdell, C.A. (1981). Science Policy Options and Priorities. In: Science and Technology Policy. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-6932-5_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-6932-5_2

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-011-6934-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-011-6932-5

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics