Skip to main content

Self Interest, Public Interest, And Legislation

  • Chapter
The Economics of Smoking

Abstract

We have suggested in several places that political processes follow an economic logic, and that in so doing the outcomes of political processes often conform quite poorly to the values and norms that are commonly presumed to inform public policy discourse. In this and in the next chapter, we explore more fully this cleavage that often separates normative or value statements about public policy from the empirical consequences of the policy measures that are actually enacted.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. See McCormick and Tollison (1981) and Peltzman (1984) for reviews of the literature.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The free rider problem refers to the issue of why an individual should join the group seeking government benefits if he cannot be excluded from the benefits once the law is passed. If all group members reason this way, no group action would be forthcoming; therefore, one object of the group is to spend resources to deter such behavior.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Olson (1965).

    Google Scholar 

  4. This analysis, however, ignores a potentially troubling question: What about rival associations with lower prices?

    Google Scholar 

  5. See Stigler (1974).

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Boadway (1979, Chapter 12) for a technical summary of these arguments.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Although the law of diminishing marginal utility applies to specific goods—a given unit purchased provides less utility to the consumer than the unit purchased before it—it does not apply to goods in general. Money represents command over goods in general. While in some individual cases, each additional dollar may generate less utility than the one before it (e.g., in the case of a monk), it is possible that in other cases the utility associated with each additional dollar actually increases. Therefore, even if we could measure and compare utility across persons—which is impossible—it is possible that we would find that the additional dollar generated more utility for the millionaire than it did for the chimney sweep. The point is simply that one cannot generalize across people about the value of additional income or command over goods and services

    Google Scholar 

  8. The case where rents are exactly dissipated represents an example of competitive rent-seeking. This does not mean, however, that all rent-seeking contests are perfectly competitive in nature. There are models where rent-seeking is imperfectly competitive in the sense that the competitive process for rents leads to over-or under dissipation of the available rents. These cases are interesting, and they are obviously generated by assumptions about limitations on the number of bidders, imperfect information, and so on.

    Google Scholar 

  9. For a more detailed argument, see Lee and Tollison (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Tullock (1968), and Niskanen (1971) for a more detailed analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Szasz (1978) has made this observation on numerous occasions.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Joseph Califano, then HEW Secretary, put the number at seven million in 1978. See Efron (1984, p. 97).

    Google Scholar 

  13. Ibid., p. 102.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Ibid., p. 160.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Ibid., p. 166.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See OMB (1990, p. 5-116).

    Google Scholar 

  17. Solmon reported that the 1976 National Health Survey showed that smokers of less than 15 cigarettes per day had an absenteeism rate of 2.6 days, compared with 4.3 days for nonsmokers, and notes that the 1979 Surgeon General’s Report indicated that male smokers of less than 11 cigarettes per day were absent less than nonsmokers, and women aged 17 and older who were presently smokers had less bed disability than nonsmokers. See Solmon (1983, pp. 1-2).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Dahl, Gunderson, and Kuehnast (1984) studied a group of 55 financial managers at Minnesota’s Farm Credit Services, and reported that smokers were significantly more productive than nonsmokers; smokers were reported to be 2.5 percent more efficient in allocating their time to assigned tasks.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Spielberger (1986, pp. 106-107) reports the results of a survey given to 424 college students who were current smokers. They indicated that reasons they continued to smoke included perceived relaxation, stimulation, and the facilitation of thinking aided by smoking.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1992 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tollison, R.D., Wagner, R.E. (1992). Self Interest, Public Interest, And Legislation. In: The Economics of Smoking. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-3892-5_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-3892-5_10

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-010-5733-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-011-3892-5

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics