Skip to main content

The Tertiary Sector and Post-Industrial Society

  • Chapter
  • 98 Accesses

Part of the book series: International Studies in the Service Economy ((ISSE,volume 3))

Abstract

In this section, we collect and examine the main themes in the analysis of service activities in the 1935–1965 period, beginning with the emergence and increasing use of the term tertiary sector.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. London, MacMillan, 1935.

    Google Scholar 

  2. London, MacMillan, 1945.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Fisher’s earlier work was in New Zealand.

    Google Scholar 

  4. The Clash of Progress and Security, pp. 25–31.

    Google Scholar 

  5. London, MacMillan, 1940.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Colin Clark draws also attention to the fact that in a period of expansion, service activities can display an extremely high rate of return.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Engel, C.: Die produtions und consumptionsverhaltnisse des Konigreiches Sachens. Zeitschrift des statistischen Bureaus des koniglich sachsischen Ministerium des Innern, (1857).

    Google Scholar 

  8. London, MacMillan, 1942.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Colin Clark and the statisticians generally are accused by Fourastié of “giving a purely formal and enumerative definition” (Le grand espoir du XXe siècle, p. 83).

    Google Scholar 

  10. “Progrès technique et répartition professionnelle de la population” (Technical progress and the relative importance of occupations) Population, 1–2, 1949.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Le grand espoir du XXe siècle, Paris, PUF, 1949, Gallimard, 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  12. For example, labour productivity in French agriculture has risen, since 1951, consistently faster than in manufacturing industry, in particular in the 1951–1973 period (by 6.3% in agriculture and 5.1% in manufacturing, resp. 4.6 and 3.5 in 1973–1984). See Dubois, P.: Ruptures de croissance et progrès technique (Turning points in growth and technical progress), Economie et Statistique, Oct. 1985. Similar increases in labour productivity in agriculture have also occurred in other countries.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Le grand espoir du XXe siècle, op. cit, p. 314.

    Google Scholar 

  14. In The Economics of 1960 (op. cit, pp. 28–29), Clark estimated the per capita tertiary income as a function of per capita total income, with a slope coefficient of 0.6985 and an intercept of -102.

    Google Scholar 

  15. For a more detailed survey of this debate, see, for example: Singelmann, J.: The Sectoral Transformation of the Labor-Force in Seven Industrial Countries, 1920–1960, Ph.D. Thesis, Austin, University of Texas, USA, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  16. In: Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations, II: Industrial Distribution of National Product and Labor Force, Economic Development and Cultural Change, supplement, july.

    Google Scholar 

  17. In: Modern Economic Growth, Rate, Structure and Spread, New Haven, Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Including mines.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Electricity only.

    Google Scholar 

  20. The first serious discussion of the delineation between goods and services, or some sort of compromise between them in the product of a specific activity, was published by: Lengelle, M: La révolution tertiaire, Paris, Génin, 1966. This book is particularly interesting because it suggests a gradation of tertiary activities, depending on how strongly the service supplied is related to the production of goods.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See: Naville, P., Cahiers d’études des sociétés industrielles et de l’automation, 5, and 7, (1963, 1965) as well as: Courthéoux, J.P.: La Répartition des Activités Economiques, Paris, Centre de recherche d’urbanisme, 1966.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Sauvy, A., op. cit, pp 66–67.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See Browning, H., Singelmann, J., The Transformation of the U.S. Labor Force: the Interaction of Industries and Occupations, Politics and Society, 8(3–4), 1978, pp. 481–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Bell, D.: The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. A Venture in Social Forecasting. New York, Basic Books, 1973, r.1976, UK edition: Heinemann Educational, 1974

    Google Scholar 

  25. In fact, as we saw before, Colin Clark’s results on this point are much less clear-cut than is generally assumed.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Bell, D., op cit, p. 125.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Bell’s forecasts are also well in line with more recent official forecasts by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The BLS reports that, with only moderate overall growth, the percentage of wage and salary earning workers who work in the manufacturing sector, fell from 24.0% in 1976 to 20.0% in 1988, and expects it to fall further to 15.6% in the year 2000. The similar percentage for “operators, fabricators and labourers” (Le., not including white-collar workers in industry), is put at 12.6 in 2000, against 14.4 in 1988. (Monthly Labor Review, Nov. 1989).

    Google Scholar 

  28. Bell, op cit, p. 15.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Richta, R.: Civilization at the Crossroads: Social and Human Implications of the Scientific and Technical Revolution. (original: Czechoslovak Academy of Science, 1967, English translation, Prague, 1968, US distribution: International Arts and Science Press, White Plains, N.Y., 1969)

    Google Scholar 

  30. Bell, D., op. cit, p. 106.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Bell, D., op cil, p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Schumpeter, Joseph Alois: Capitalism, socialism and democracy, Fourth edition: New York, Harper & Row, 1950 (UK: Allen & Unwin, 1954), p. 152.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Baumol, W: Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of an Urban Crisis. American Economic Review, 57, June 1967, pp. 415–26.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Baumol, W., Blackman, S. and Wolff, E.: Unbalanced Growth Revisited: Asymptotic Stagnancy and New Evidence, American Economic Review, 75, 1985 pp. 806–816.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Baumol, W., Blackman, S., and Wolf, E.: Productivity and American Leadership, Cambridge, MIT Press, 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  36. There is, however, a large scope for economies through technology in government, as shown by T. Stanback in his book Computerization and the Transformation of Employment, Boulder, Westview Press, 1987.

    Google Scholar 

  37. According to T.J. Noyelle and T.M. Stanback (1990), productivity measurements in the U.S. are seriously distorted or largely meaningless for series covering nearly two thirds of GDP originated in services.

    Google Scholar 

  38. The most critical point is the likelihood of the constancy of the inputs ratio.assessment of America’s strength. However, services are analysed on the same theoretical basis: cost disease and asymptotic stagnancy.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Paris, Le Seuil (also 4th ed., 1969).

    Google Scholar 

  40. Paris, Le Seuil, 1964.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Paris, Le Seuil, 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Paris, Denoel, 1969.

    Google Scholar 

  43. The concept of service relations was developed in a very innovative way by Erving Goffman in Asylums (Anchor Books, Doubleday & Co, New York, 1961). Goffman based part of his work on the pioneering works of Talcott Parsons (“The Professionals in the Social Structure” Social Forces, 17, (1939), reprinted in Essays in Sociological Theory Pure and Applied, The Free Press, New York, 1949), as well as on Everett C. Hughes (Men and their Work, The Free Press, New York, 1958), and Howard S. Becker (“The Professional Dance Musician and His Audience”, American Journal of Sociology LVII (1951). See also the remarkable book by Eliot Freidson Profession of Medicine, Harper & Row, New York, 1970.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Galbraith, J.K.: The New Industrial State, Signet Books, New American Library, New York, 1967 (UK: Hamish Hamilton, 1967, r (Pelican), 1969, 1970)

    Google Scholar 

  45. V.R. Fuchs (1968), and subsequently J. Singelmann (1974), criticised Galbraith for the indeed astonishing disregard for a group of activities which employed more than half of the working population.

    Google Scholar 

  46. We shall come back to this point in relation to the works of T. Noyelle and T.M. Stanback, to be discussed in the next chapter.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Compare Chapter 25 of The New Industrial State with the concluding chapter of Bell’s book.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Praderie, Michel: Les tertiaires Paris, Le Seuil, 1968.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Courthéoux, J.P.: La répartition des activités économique, op cit.

    Google Scholar 

  50. New-York, Columbia University Press, 1968.

    Google Scholar 

  51. “Productivity Trends in the Goods and Service Sector” (1964, occasional paper n¡ã 89); “The Growing Importance of the Service Industries” (1965, occasional paper n¡ã 96).

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Kuznets, 1957, op. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Note that, in these studies, Fuchs classifies transport, communication and public utilities in the goods sector.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Bell cites Fuchs on a number of places.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Singelmann, J., op. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See the last chapter of Singelmann’s thesis.

    Google Scholar 

  57. We already mentioned that there were others who paid less attention to that dimension (e.g. Galbraith).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1992 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Delaunay, JC., Gadrey, J. (1992). The Tertiary Sector and Post-Industrial Society. In: Services in Economic Thought. International Studies in the Service Economy, vol 3. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-2960-2_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-2960-2_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-010-5314-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-011-2960-2

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics