Advertisement

Equilibrium Political Inaction in a Democracy

Chapter
Part of the International Studies in Economics and Econometrics book series (ISEE, volume 28)

Abstract

The suppression of political demands is usually associated with dictatorships. In democracies, individuals are typically free to speak out on political issues, to organize or participate in demonstrations against the government, write letters to newspapers, and so forth, and their right to do so is protected by a judicial system which is independent of the government. Nevertheless, political freedom is not complete in any democracy, and certain overt restrictions are typically imposed. These overt restrictions are usually imposed on freedom of speech where significant external costs might result. In this category are the restrictions imposed by many jurisdictions against “hate” literature; libel laws; restrictions on the discrimination of pornographic literature, to engage in criminal conspiracies, and so forth. More severe restrictions are often imposed on speech which has commercial rather than a political purpose.’ In Canada, for example there is no law banning the activity of prostitution, but therearelaws against the soliciting of customers by prostitutes.

Keywords

Political Party Ideal Point Median Voter American Political Science Review Ideological Position 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Bibliography

  1. Aldrich, John H. “A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activism.”American Political Science Review77 (1983): 974–990CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alesina, Alberto. “Credibility and Policy Convergence in a Two-Party System with Rational Voters”American Economic Review78 (1988): 796–805Google Scholar
  3. Breton, Albert, and Wintrobe, Ronald. “Freedom of Speech vs Efficient Regulation in Markets for Ideas.”Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization17 (1992): 217–239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Canadian Criminal Cases 38 C.C.C. (3d). Reference re Criminal Code SS 193 and 195. 1(1)(c)Google Scholar
  5. Coase, Ronald. “The Market for Goods and the Market for Ideas.” American Economic Review64 (1977: 384–391Google Scholar
  6. Enelow, James M., and Melvin J. Hinich. “Ideology, Issues, and the Spatial Theory of Elections.”American Political Science Review76 (1982): 493–501CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Huntington, Samuel. No Easy Choice: Political Participation in Developing Countries. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1976Google Scholar
  8. Powell, G. Bingham, Jr. “Extremist Parties and Political Turmoil: Two Puzzles.” American Journal of Political Science30 (1986: 357–378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Sartori, GiovanniParties and Party Systems.New York: Cambridge University Press, 1976Google Scholar
  10. Wintrobe, Ronald. “Political Competition and the Rise of Dictatorship” in A Breton, G. Galeotti, P. Salmon and R. Wintrobe, eds.The Competitive State.Kluwer Academic Press, 1990Google Scholar
  11. Wittman, Donald. “Parties as Utility Maximizers.”American Political Science Review67 (1973)Google Scholar
  12. “Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories.”American Political Science Review.77 (1983): 142–157CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 1993

Authors and Affiliations

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations