Skip to main content

Eight Frameworks for Regulation

  • Chapter
Book cover Technological Risk Assessment

Part of the book series: NATO ASI Series ((NSSE,volume 81))

Abstract

The Frameworks used to guide analysis and the decisions made regarding proposed health and safety regulations are inextricably linked. For example, if an agency is required by law to ban any substance shown to be a carcinogen, little or nothing is gained by an elaborate analysis of the economic and other implications of alternative decisions. The decision framework establishes priorities among issues and changes the way both regulators and nongovernmental decision makers view health and safety issues. Choosing a decision framework and using it consistently is perhaps the most important device for influencing the billions of decisions governing health and safety that are outside the control of federal regulators. Failure to appreciate the importance of the decision framework is the root of much of the criticism of social regulation. Legislation such as the Toxic Substances Control Act; the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act; and the Consumer Product Safety Act requires analysis of benefits, costs, and risks in formulating a regulation1. Unfortunately, subject areas such as carcinogenicity lack a firm scientific foundation for an analysis for those areas having a scientific foundation. Legislation such as the Delaney Clause is highly specific in requiring a ban2, but occasionally this action is so counter to public desires that the agency is condemned for carrying out the legislation, for example, for banning saccharin.

From, The Strategy of Social Regulation: Deci si on Frameworks for Policy, Brookings Institution, 1981. Used by Permission.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Michael S. Baram, “Regulation of Health, Safety and Environmental Quality and the Use of Cost-Benefit Analysis,” pp. 46, 59–60, 75–76; and L. E. Erickson, “Issues and Experiences in Applying Benefit Cost Analysis to Health and Safety Standards,” app. A and F.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The so-called Delaney Clause resulted from hearings held by Congressman James Delaney of New York and is found in the Food Additives Amendment of 1958 to the Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act of 1938 (72 Stat. 1786). It states in part that “no additive shall be deemed to be safe if it is found… to induce cancer in man or animal.”

    Google Scholar 

  3. Arranging the frameworks is not so simple. For example, risk- benefit analysis requires as much information as benefit-cost analysis, although it is less formal. While more than a single dimension is involved, the ordering is roughly accurate. See the bibliography for additional references.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Gerard Debreu. Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium; and Kenneth J. Arrow and F. H. Hahn, General Competitive Analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Kenneth J. Arrow, “Limited Knowledge and Economic Analysis.” pp. 1–10; and Jacques H. Dreze, ed., Allocation under Uncertainty: Equilibrium and Optimality.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Theodore F. Keeler, “Domestic Trunk Airline Deregulation: An Economic Evaluation,” pp. 75–149; and Paul W. Mavoy and John W. Snow, eds., Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform, p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  7. George J. Stigler. The Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation; and Milton Friedman. Capitalism and Freedom.

    Google Scholar 

  8. John Kenneth Galbraith. Economics and the Public Purpose; Galbraith. The New Industrial State; and Robert L. Heilbroner. The Limits of American Capitalism, pp. 1–61.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Friedman. Capitalism and Freedom; and Stigler. The Citizen and the State.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Interagency Regulatory Liaison Group, “Scientific Bases for Identifying Potential Carcinogens and Estimating Their Risks,” pp. 22–61; National Academy of Sciences. Food Safety Policy: Scientific and Societal Considerations, pp. 5–21 through 5–25; and “Identification, Classification and Regulation of Toxic Substances Posing a Potential Occupational Carcinogenic Risk,” Federal Register, vol. 42 (October 4, 1977), pp. 54156–67.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Richard A. Merrill, “Regulating Carcinogens in Food: A Legislator’s Guide to the Food Safety Provisions of the Federal Food, Drug and Cosmetic Act,” pp. 245–46; Peter Barton Hutt, “Food Regulation,” pp. 521–24, and 553; and Richard A. Merrill “Federal Regulation of Cancer-Causing Chemicals,” chap. 2: “FDA Regulation of Environmental Contaminants,” pp. 21–25.

    Google Scholar 

  12. NAS, Food Safety Policy; Victor R. Fuchs, “Some Economic Aspects of Mortality in Developed Countries;” and Fuchs, “Economics, Health, and Post Industrial Society,” pp. 153–82.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Lester B. Lave and others, “Economic Impact of Preventive Medicine,” pp. 675–705; Lester B. Lave and Eugene P. Seskin. Air Pollution and Human Health, chap. 10; and Robert S. Smith, Compensating Wage Differentials and Public Policy: A Review.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Paul F. Deisler, Jr., “Dealing with Industrial Health Risks,” p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  15. “Chemical Compounds in Food-Producinq Animals,” Federal Register, vol. 42 (February 22, 1977), p. 10427.

    Google Scholar 

  16. “National Emission Standards for Identifying, Assessing and Regulating Airborne Substances Posing a Risk of Cancer,” Federal Register, vol. 42 (October 10, 1978), p. 58660.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Larry E. Ruff, “Federal Environmental Regulation,” pp. 279–82, 299–303.

    Google Scholar 

  18. U. S. Food and Drug Administration and the U. S. Department of Agriculture, “FDA’s and USDA’s Action Regarding Nitrite.”

    Google Scholar 

  19. Gio Batta Gori, “The Regulation of Carcinogenic Hazards,” pp. 256–61;.J. L. Radoniski, “Evaluating the Role of Environmental Chemicals in Human Cancer,” pp. 27–44; memorandum, Arthur C. Upton, Director of the National Cancer Institute, to the commissioner of the Food and Drug Administration, “Quantitative Risk Assessment;” and National Academy of Sciences. Saccharin: Technical Assessment of Risks and Benefits, p. ES-5.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See NAS, Food Safety Policy, pp. 4–17, 8–5; and Oliver E. Williamson, “Public Policy and Saccharin: The Decision Process Approach and Its Alternatives,” in Robert Crandall and Lester B. Lave, eds., The Scientific Basis of Health, Safety, and Environmental Regulation.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Smith, “Compensating Wage Differentials and Public Policy.”

    Google Scholar 

  22. Ibid.; and Richard Thaler and Sherwin Rosen, “The Value of Saving a Life: Evidence from the Labor Market,” pp. 265–98. The various studies attempt to control for other factors affecting pay, such as years of training.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Lester B. Lave and Lester Silverman, “Economic Costs of Energy-Related Environmental Pollution,” pp. 619–23.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Chauncey Starr, “Benefit-Cost Studies in Sociotechnical Systems;” Starr, “Social Benefit Versus Technological Risk;” NAS, Product Safety; Cyril Comar, “SO2 Regulations;” Richard Wilson, “Direct Testimony in the Matter of Proposed Regulations… for Toxic Substances Posing a Potential Occupational Carcinogenic Risk;” Bernard L. Cohen, “Society Valuation of Life Saving in Radiation Protection and Other Contents;” Thomas H. Jukes, “Diethylstilbestrol in Beef Production: What Is the Risk?” and Richard C. Schwing, “Expenditures to Reduce Mortality Risk and Increase Longevity.”

    Google Scholar 

  25. Personal communication with Charles L. Schultze. See U. S. Department of Commerce Regulatory Reform Seminar: Proceedings and Background Paper, pp. 17–31; Christopher C. Duth, “Constraining Regulatory Costs,” pt. 1: “The White House Review Programs,” pp. 13–36; Duth, “Constraining Regulatory Costs,” pt. 2: “The Regulatory Budget,” pp. 29–44; and William Nordhaus and Robert Litan, “A Regulatory Budget for the United States.”

    Google Scholar 

  26. National Academy of Scienes. Analytical Studies for the U. S. Environmental Protection Agency, vol. 2: Decision Making in the Environmental Protection Agency, app. D; Baruch Fischoff and others, “Approaches to Acceptable Risk,” pp. 169–204; and Baram, “Requlation of Health, Safety, and Environmental Quality.”

    Google Scholar 

  27. Benefit-cost analysis usually assumes fixed prices, wages, and discount rates. If the scope of project or projects being analyzed is sufficiently large, however, prices and discount rate must be determined within the analysis. Thus, applying benefit-cost analysis to all health and safety decisions made by the Food and Drug Administration would require a determination of the appropriate discount rate and would probably specify more projects than the agency could afford to do immediately. In this sense, the regulatory budget framework is a specialization of benefit-cost. analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Paul M. Newberne, “Dietary Nitrite in the Rat.” See also Newberne, “Nitrite Promotes Lymphoma Incidence in Rats,” pp. 1079–81; Council on Agricultural Science and Technology, “Comments on the Newberne Report on the Effect of Dietary Nitrite in the Rat;” Food Safety and Quality. Hearings, pp. 5–28, 176–80, 131–34, 236–38, 356–64; Comptroller General of the United States, Does Nitrite Cause Cancer? Concerns about Validity of FDA-Sponsored Study Delay Answer.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See, for example, Howard Raiffa. Decision Analysis: Introductory Lectures on Choice under Uncertainty.

    Google Scholar 

  30. For a discussion of this point see Richard Zeckhauser and Albert Nichols, “The Occupational Safety and Health Administration: An Overview,” app., pp. 161–248; and National Academy of Sciences. Decision flaking for Regulating Chemicals in the Environment.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Lave and Seskin. Air Pollution and Human Health, p. 212; and U. S. Environmental Protection Agency. Protecting Visibility: An EPA Report to Congress, pp. 11–12 through 11–17.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1984 Martinus Nijhoff Publishers, The Hague

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lave, L. (1984). Eight Frameworks for Regulation. In: Ricci, P.F., Sagan, L.A., Whipple, C.G. (eds) Technological Risk Assessment. NATO ASI Series, vol 81. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-6155-5_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-6155-5_8

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-009-6157-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-009-6155-5

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics