Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Studies in Industrial Organization ((SIOR,volume 9))

  • 92 Accesses

Abstract

Consumer welfare as the single goal of antitrust is analyzed by means of neoclassical microeconomics, which means that perfect competition and monopoly serve as standards of reference.1 Neither perfect competition nor monopoly in the structural sense are seen as states that should be reached. They simply serve as a basis from which to depart for the purpose of analysis and thereby should contribute to analytical clarity. The guiding concept of antitrust policy is not an ideal market structure to be reached but the maximization of consumer welfare as a performance criterion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Cf. Scherer, Frederie M., The Posnerian Harvest: Separating Wheat from Chaff, 86 The Yale Law Journal 974 ff. (1977), 995: Also I have been unable to find an explicit definition (of efficiency)....”

    Google Scholar 

  2. Cf. Nelson, Richard L., Comment on Paper by Posner, 127 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 949 ff. (1979), 949.

    Google Scholar 

  3. A good survey on the steps in the development from price theory to competition theory is offered by Zohlnhüfer, Werner, Wettbewerb — Modell und Wirklichkeit, in: Andreae, Clemens-August, and Werner Benisch (eds.), Wettbewerbsordnung und Wettbewerbsrealität, Köln et al. 1982, pp. 15 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Cf. esp. Chamberlin, Edward H., The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Cambridge, Mass. 1933; Robinson, Joan, The Economics of Imperfect Competition, London 1933, and Triffin, Robert, Monopolistic Competition and General Equilibrium Theory, Cambridge, Mass. 1940.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Cf. Clark, John M., Toward a Concept of Workable Competition, 30 The American Economic Review 241 ff. (1940); idem, Competition as a Dynamic Process, Washington D.C. 1961.

    Google Scholar 

  6. On this concept cf. esp. Kantzenbach, Erhard, Die Funktionsfähigkeit des Wettbewerbs, 2nd rev. ed., Göttingen 1967, refering to Almarin Phillips, Market Structure, Organization, and Performance, Cambridge, Mass. 1962.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Cf. Kuznets, Simon S., Economic Change, New York 1953.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Harris, Robert G., and Thomas M. Jorde, Market Definition in the Merger Guidelines: Implications for Antitrust Enforcement, 71 California Law Review 464 ff. (1983), 468.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Analogous to Neale, Alan D., and D.G. Goyder, The Antitrust Laws of the USA: A Study of Competition Enforced by Law, 3rd ed., Cambridge et al. 1980, 439 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Quoted after Pitofsky, Roben, The Political Content of Antitrust, 127 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1051 ff. (1979), 1063.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Cf. Kauper, Thomas E., The Goals of United States Antitrust Policy — The Current Debate, 136 Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 408 ff. (1980), 420 who critically comments on Bork’s criticism of the jurisdiction as follows: “Whether they are ‘wrong’ or part of a ‘deviant’ theme (as Bork states), is ultimately a question of judgment.”

    Google Scholar 

  12. Cf. Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. U.S., 1958 CCH Trade Cases § 68,961, pp. 73,862 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Cf. Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 1962 CCH Trade Cases § 70,366, pp. 76,479 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Cf. Mestmäcker, Ernst-Joachim, Competition Policy and Antitrust: Some Comparative Observations, 136 Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 387 ff. (1980).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Cf. Posner, Richard A., Economics, Politics, and the Reading of Statutes and the Constitution, 49 University of Chicago Law Review 263 ff. (1982), 269, and Easterbrook, Frank H., Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98 Harvard Law Review 4 ff. (1984), 15.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Cf. Kallfass, Hermann H., Die Chicago School — Eine Skizze des “neuen” amerikanischen Ansatzes für die Wettbewerbspolitik, 30 Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb 596 ff. (1980), 599 f.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Cf. Posner, Richard A., Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective, Chicago 1976, 8 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Shepherd, William G., The Treatment of Market Power, New York 1975, 119. Cf. also Scherer, Industrial market structure..., op. cit., 94, who states that “with few exceptions, the minimum optimal plant scale revealed in studies of American manufacturing industries has been small relative to industry size”. Idem at p. 95: “We conclude then that economies of scale at the plant level do not in the vast majority of instances necessitate high national concentration levels for U.S. manufacturing industries.”

    Google Scholar 

  19. Cf. Shepherd, William G., The Economics of Industrial Organization, 2nd ed., Englewood Cliffs, N.J. 1985, 181–185, and Scherer, Industrial market structure..., op. cit., 91–98.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Cf. Leibenstein, Harvey, Allocative Efficiency vs. “X-Efficiency“, 35 The American Economic Review 392 ff. (1966).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Cf. Siegfried, John I., and Wheeler, Edwin H., Cost Efficiency and Monopoly Power: A Survey, 2 Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 25 ff. (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  22. Stigler, George J., The X-istence of X-Efficiency, 66 The American Economic Review 213 ff. (1976), 213.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Cf. Di Lorenzo, Thomas J., Corporate Management, Property Rights and the X-istence of X-efficiency, 48 Southern Economic Journal 116 ff. (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  24. 79 Cf. De Alessi, Louis, Property Rights, Transaction Costs, and X-Efficiency: An Essay in Economic Theory, 73 The American Economic Review 64 ff. (1983).

    Google Scholar 

  25. Cf. Areeda, Phillip, and Donald F. Turner, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles, vol. 1, Boston, Toronto 1978, 9.

    Google Scholar 

  26. For a detailed survey on these different mechanisms of coordination cf. Ouchi, Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans, supra, 129 ff.; for the basic work on different mechanisms of economic coordination, cf. Coase, Ronald, Tbe Nature of the Firm, 4 Economica 386 ff. (1937).

    Google Scholar 

  27. Williamson, Oliver E., Assessing Vertical Market Restrictions: Antitrust Ramifications of the Transaction Cost Approach, 127 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 953 ff. (1979), 993.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Cf. Williamson, Oliver, Economies as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs, 58 The American Economic Review 18 ff. (1968).

    Google Scholar 

  29. Böbel, Ingo, Wettbewerb und Industriestruktur: Industrial Organization — Forschung im Überblick, Berlin et al. 1984, 210 (translated by the authors).

    Google Scholar 

  30. Cf. esp. Böbel, Wettbewerb und Industriestruktur, op. cit., 213 ff., and as well Möschel, Wemhard, Antitrust and Economic Analysis of Law, 140 Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 156 ff. (1984), 164 f.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Cf. Williamson, Oliver E., Economies as an Antitrust Defense Revisited, in: Jaequemin, Alexis P, and Henk W. de Jong (eds.), Welfare Aspects of Industrial Markets, Leiden 1977, pp. 237 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Cf. Sullivan, Lawrence A., Handbook of the Law of Antitrust, St. Paul, Minn. 1977, 3.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Lipsey, R.G., and Kelvin Lancaster, The General Theory of Second Best, 24 The Review of Economic Studies 11 ff. (1956), 11.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Cf. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox, op. cit., 109; for a survey on the basic problems of external effects see Boadway and Wildasin, op. cit., 60 ff. and 105 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Schmalensee, Richard, Another Look at Market Power, 95 Harvard Law Review 1789 ff. (1982), 1806.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Weiss, Leonard, Quantitive Studies of Industrial Organization, in: Intriligator, Michael D. (ed.), Frontiers of Quantitative Economics, Amsterdarn, Oxford 1971, pp. 362 ff., 363.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Weiss, Quantitative Studies, op. cit., 371; because more recent studies found a negative relationship between profitability and concentration, the emphasis of recent studies has been on market share and profitability, cf. Gale, Bradley J., and Ben S. Branch, Concentration vs. Market Share: Which Determines Performance and Why Does It Matter?, 27 Antitrust Bulletin 83 ff. (1982), and Mueller, Dennis C., Profits in the Long Run, Cambridge, Mass. 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Cf. Greer, Industrial Organization and Public Policy, op. cit., 405–407; and Weiss, Leonard W., The Coneentration-Profits Relationship and Antitrust, in: Goldschmid, Harvey, et al. (eds.), Industrial Concentration: The New Learning, Boston, Toronto 1974, pp. 184 ff., 196–200.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Cf. Fisher, Franklin M., and John J. McGowan, On the Misuse of Accounting Rates of Return to Infer Monopoly Profits, 73 The American Economic Review 82 ff. (1983); and Long, William F., and David J. Ravenscraft, The Misuse of Accounting Rates of Return: A Comment, 74 The American Economic Review 494 ff. (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  40. For a survey cf. again Leamer, Edward E., Sensitivity Analysis Would Help, 75 The American Economic Review 308 ff. (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  41. Benston, The Validity of Profits-Structure Studies, supra, 64; and the rejoinder, Scherer, Frederic M., et al., The Validity of Studies with Line of Business Data: Comment, 75 The American Economic Review 205 ff. (1987), 209.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Cf. Abell, Derek F., and John S. Rammond, Strategic Market Planning: Problems and Analytical Approaches, Englewood Cliffs, NJ., 1979, 289.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Cf. Buzzell et al., Market Share..., supra; Gale/Branch. Concentration versus Market Share..., supra; Martin, Steven, Market, Firm and Economic Perfonnance, New York 1983; and for an early work, Shepherd, William G., The Elements of Market Structure, 54 Tbe Review ofEconomics and Statistics 25 ff. (1972).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Cf. Clarke, Roger, Stephen Davies and Michael Waterson, The Profitability-Concentration Relation: Market Power or Efficiency?, 32 The Journal of Industrial Economics 435 ff. (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  45. Cf. Amato, Louis, and Ronald P. Wilder, The Effects of Firm Size on Profit Rates in U.S. Manufacturing, 52 Southern Economic Journal 181 ff. (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  46. Cf. Mueller, Willard F., A New Attack on Antitrust: The Chicago Case, 18 Antitrust Law and Economics Review 29 ff. (1986), 40.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Peltzman, Sam, The Gains and Losses from Industrial Concentration, 20 The Journal of Law and Economics 229 ff. (1977).

    Google Scholar 

  48. Cf. Scherer, Frederic M., The Causes and Consequences of Rising Industrial Concentration, 22 Journal of Law and Economics 191 ff. (1979).

    Google Scholar 

  49. Cf. Solow, Robert M., Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function, 39 The Review of Economics and Statistics 312 ff. (1957), and Denison, Edward, Accounting for United States Economic Growth: 1929–69, Washington, D.C. 1974, 131–137.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Cf. Kamien, Morton I., and Nancy L. Schwartz, Market Structure and Innovation: A Survey, 13 Journal of Economic Literature 16 ff. (1975), 16–18.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Mansfield, Edwin, Industrial Organization and Technological Change: Recent Econometric Findings, in: John V. Craven (ed.), Industrial Organization, Antitrust, and Public Policy, Boston 1983, pp. 129 ff., 131.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Cf. Jewkes, J., D. Sawers, and R. Stillerman, The Sources of Invention, 2nd ed., London, New York 1969, pp. 66 f. and 73.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Quoted from Adams, Walter, and James W. Brock, The “New Learning” and the Euthanasia of Antitrust, 74 California Law Review 1516 ff. (1986), 1560.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Cf. Blair, John M., Economic Concentration: Structure, Behavior and Public Policy, New York 1972, 87–113, and Schmidt, Wettbewerbspolitik und Kartellrecht, op. cit., 97 f.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Cf. Levin, R. C., W. M. Cohen and D. C. Mowrey, R & D Appropriability, Opportunity, and Market Structure: New Evidence on some Schumpeterian Hypothesis, 75 The American Economic Review 20 ff. (1985), which are scrutinizing the neo-Schumpeterian hypothesis by means of better, more recent data.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Cf. Mansfield, Edwin, Technological Change and Market Structure: An Empirical Study, 73 The American Economic Review 205 ff. (1983), 205–209, esp. at p. 208.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1989 Kluwer Academic Publishers

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Schmidt, I.L.O., Rittaler, J.B. (1989). The Chicago School’s Approach to Antitrust Theory. In: A Critical Evaluation of the Chicago School of Antitrust Analysis. Studies in Industrial Organization, vol 9. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-2567-0_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-009-2567-0_4

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-010-7660-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-009-2567-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics