Skip to main content

Conceptual Framework for Nonmarket Valuation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation

Part of the book series: The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources ((ENGO,volume 13))

Abstract

This chapter provides an overview of the theoretical foundations of nonmarket valuation. The chapter first develops a model of individual choice where private goods are freely chosen but environmental goods are rationed from the individual’s perspective. The model is used to define compensating and equivalent welfare measures for changes in prices and environmental goods. These welfare measures form the basis of the environmental values researchers seek to measure through nonmarket valuation. The chapter discusses the travel cost model with and without weak complementarity, the household production model, the hedonic model, and the general concept of passive-use value. The individual choice model is extended to a dynamic framework and separately to choice under uncertainty. Finally the chapter develops welfare measures associated with averting expenditures and random utility models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    These topics alone could constitute an entire book, but the treatment of each must be brief. For those launching a career in this area, Freeman (1993) and Hanley et al. (1997) are recommended.

  2. 2.

    The utility function is ordinal in the sense that many different functions could be used to equally represent a given preference ordering. For a complete discussion of preference orderings and their representations by utility functions, see Kreps (1990) or Varian (1992).

  3. 3.

    One can choose goods that have environmental quality attributes, e.g., air quality and noise. These goods are rationed in the sense that an individual cannot unilaterally improve ambient air quality or noise level at his or her current house. One can move to a new location where air quality is better but cannot determine the level of air quality at his or her current location.

  4. 4.

    It may be the case that one has to pay for \(Q^{0}\). Rather than including this payment in the budget constraint, he or she can simply consider income to already be adjusted by this amount. Because the levels of the nonmarket goods are not individually chosen, there is no need to include payments for nonmarket goods in the budget constraint.

  5. 5.

    To clarify notation, \(p \cdot X = p_{1} x_{1} + p_{2} x_{2} + \cdots + p_{n} x_{n} ,\) where p i is the price of market good i.

  6. 6.

    Interest over the difference in size between C and E has received considerable attention. For price changes, Willig (1976) provided an analysis. For quantity changes, see Randall and Stoll (1980) and Hanemann (1991). Hanemann (1999) provided a comprehensive and technical review of these issues. From the perspective of measurement, there is a general consensus that it is more difficult to measure E, particularly in stated preference analysis.

  7. 7.

    Roy’s identity states that the derivative of the expenditure function with respect to price i is simply the Hicksi demand for good i. The fundamental theorem of calculus allows one to write the difference of two differentiable functions as the integral over the derivative of that function.

  8. 8.

    An example is the case of weak substitutability provided in Feenberg and Mills (1980).

  9. 9.

    The classic citations in this area are Griliches (1971), Rosen (1974), and Palmquist (1984).

  10. 10.

    Cicchetti and Wilde (1992) had contended that Krutilla’s (1967) arguments, and hence passive-use value, only apply to highly unique resources. However, Krutilla (Footnote 5, p. 778) noted that “Uniqueness need not be absolute for the following arguments to hold.”

  11. 11.

    In discussing trends, Krutilla (1967) gave the example of the evolution from a family that car camps to a new generation of backpackers, canoe cruisers, and cross-country skiers.

  12. 12.

    The terms “option value,” “preservation value,” “stewardship value,” “bequest value,” “inherent value,” “intrinsic value,” “vicarious consumption value,” and “intangible value” have been used to describe passive-use values. Carson et al. (1999) noted that these are motivations rather than distinct values.

  13. 13.

    See Carson (2012), Portney (1994), Hanemann (1994), and Diamond and Hausman (1994).

  14. 14.

    The special case where g(X, Q) = g(X) has been referred to as “the hopeless case” because the ordinary demands are independent of the levels of Q, leaving no hope for recovering the value of Q from demand data.

  15. 15.

    Dividing passive-use value into bequest value, existence value, and the like will provide similarly inconclusive results. The decompositions will not be unique.

  16. 16.

    Maler et al. (1994) similarly defined use values as those values that rely on observed market behavior for inference.

  17. 17.

    For examples, see Fisher and Krutilla (1975), Horowitz (1996), Porter (1982), and Schelling (1997).

  18. 18.

    Time is an important dimension, and uncertainty transcends time. However, there is not enough space to cover time and uncertainty together.

  19. 19.

    In accordance with standard probability theory, F consists of a sample space of outcomes and a probability law for all subsets of the sample space that satisfies the properties of a probability measure.

  20. 20.

    Influential papers in this area include Graham (1981), Weisbrod (1964), Schmalensee (1972), and Arrow and Fisher (1974). Freeman (1993) provided a fairly comprehensive overview.

  21. 21.

    In Chap. 5 of their book, Bockstael and McConnell (2007) provided an excellent overview of welfare measures in discrete-choice models.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. & Fisher, A. C. (1974). Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88, 312-319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1993). Nobel lecture: The economic way of looking at behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 101, 385-409.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N. E. & McConnell, K. E. (2007). Environmental and resource valuation with revealed preferences: A theoretical guide to empirical models. Vol. 7 of I. J. Bateman (Ed.), The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources series. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braeutigam, R. R. & Noll, R. G. (1984). The regulation of surface freight transportation: The welfare effects revisited. Review of Economics and Statistics, 66, 80-87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, R. T. (2012). Contingent valuation: A practical alternative when prices aren’t available. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 27-42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson, R. T., Flores, N. E. & Mitchell, R. C. (1999). The theory and measurement of passive-use value. In I. J. Bateman & K. G. Willis (Eds.), Valuing environmental preferences: Theory and practice of the contingent valuation method in the US, EU, and developing countries (pp. 97-130). Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cicchetti, C. J. & Wilde, L. L. (1992). Uniqueness, irreversibility, and the theory of nonuse values. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 74, 1121-1125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. & Hausman, J. A. (1994). Contingent valuation: Is some number better than no number? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (4), 45-64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenberg, D. &. Mills, E. S. (1980). Measuring the benefits of water pollution abatement. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, A. C. & Krutilla, J. V. (1975). Resource conservation, environmental preservation, and the rate of discount. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89, 358-370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, M. A. III. (1993). The measurement of environmental and resource values: Theory and methods. Washington, DC: RFF Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham, D. A. (1981). Cost-benefit analysis under uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 71, 715-725.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1971). Price indexes and quality change: Studies in new methods of measurement. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. (1991). Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: How much can they differ? The American Economic Review, 81, 635-647.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. (1994). Valuing the environment through contingent valuation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (4), 19-43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. (1995). Contingent valuation and economics. In K. G. Willis & J. T. Corkindale (Eds.), Environmental valuation: New perspectives (pp. 79-117). Wallingford, Oxfordshire, United Kingdom: CAB International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. (1999). Neo-classical economic theory and contingent valuation. In I. J. Bateman & K. G. Willis (Eds.), Valuing environmental preferences: Theory and practice of the contingent valuation method in the US, EU, and developing countries (pp. 42-96). Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanley, N., Shogren, J. F. & White, B. (Eds.). (1997). Environmental economics: In theory and practice. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. A. (1981). Exact consumer’s surplus and deadweight loss. The American Economic Review, 71, 662-676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1943). The four consumer’s surpluses. The Review of Economic Studies, 31-41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, J. K. (1996). Environmental policy under a non-market discount rate. Ecological Economics, 16, 73-78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. M. (1990). A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krutilla, J. V. (1967). Conservation reconsidered. The American Economic Review, 57, 777-786.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maler, K.-G. (1974). Environmental economics: A theoretical inquiry. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maler, K.-G., Gren, I.-M. & Folke, C. (1994). Multiple use of environmental resources: A household production function approach to valuing natural capital. In A. Jansson, M. Hammer, C. Folke & R. Costanza (Eds.), Investing in natural capital: The ecological economics approach to sustainability (pp. 233-249). Washington, DC: Island Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, K. E. (1983). Existence and bequest value. In R. D. Rowe & L. G. Chestnut (Eds.), Managing air quality and scenic resources at national parks and wilderness areas (pp. 254-264). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmquist, R. B. (1984). Estimating the demand for the characteristics of housing. Review of Economics and Statistics, 66, 394-404.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, R. C. (1982). The new approach to wilderness preservation through benefit-cost analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 9, 59-80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Portney, P. R. (1994). The contingent valuation debate: Why economists should care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (4), 3-17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randall, A. & Stoll, J. R. (1980). Consumer’s surplus in commodity space. The American Economic Review, 70, 449-455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34-55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1997). Intergenerational discounting. In T. H. Tietenberg (Ed.), The economics of global warming (pp. 607-613). Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. (1972). Option demand and consumer’s surplus: Valuing price changes under uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 62, 813-824.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (1992). Microeconomic analysis (3rd ed.). New York: W. W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vartia, Y. O. (1983). Efficient methods of measuring welfare change and compensated income in terms of ordinary demand functions. Econometrica, 51, 79-98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A. (1964). Collective-consumption services of individual-consumption goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 78, 471-477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willig, R. D. (1976). Consumer’s surplus without apology. The American Economic Review, 66, 589-597.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicholas E. Flores .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Science+Business Media B.V. (outside the USA)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Flores, N.E. (2017). Conceptual Framework for Nonmarket Valuation. In: Champ, P., Boyle, K., Brown, T. (eds) A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation. The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources, vol 13. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-7104-8_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-7104-8_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-007-7103-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-007-7104-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics