Skip to main content

Private Versus Public Quality Schemes for Origin-Labelled Products: Insights from the Karakul Pelts and Camdeboo Mohair Industries

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Developing Geographical Indications in the South

Abstract

This chapter explores aspects around the public nature of GIs and the associated debate on the need for public intervention in supporting GI development and implementation. The discussion draws on the commonalities and differences between the Camdeboo mohair and Karakul pelts cases, both of which are Southern African luxury clothing products with sophisticated quality management systems. The cases are both endemic industries with a strong link to the region but which are not linked to national GI protection schemes. They differ significantly however with respect to their approach to investment in the common resources underlying the reputation of the origin based product as well as with respect to the management of the collective reputation. The chapter provides insights into the implications of public versus privately driven origin based quality schemes, particularly with respect to potential exclusionary dynamics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Act 47 of 1996.

  2. 2.

    BKB was formed on 1 July 1975 with the amalgamation of three farmersā€™ organisations, namely Farmersā€™ Co-operative Wool and Produce Union Limited (FCU), Boere-Saamwerk Beperk (BSB) and Koƶperatiewe Wolmaatskappy Beperk (KWB). FCU was established in 1919, BSB in 1920 and KWB in 1927. Boeremakelaars (Koƶperatief) Beperk was registered in 1975. On 30 June 1998, Boeremakelaars (Koƶperatief) Beperk was transformed into a full-fledged company with shareholders. This company is known as BKB Limited.

  3. 3.

    The company does not contract for the buying or selling of the mohair BUT for the right to process and sell the specific raw mohair, intermediary or final products as made from ā€˜Camdeboo Mohairā€™ (provided that this is indeed the case).

  4. 4.

    Stucken and SAMIL (both South African companies) account for 80Ā % of first stage world mohair processing globally.

  5. 5.

    SA Mohair Brokers Ltd trading as Cape Mohair & Wool (CMW).

  6. 6.

    This collective dimension attached to a territory contrasts with the traditionally private nature of the intellectual property rights (IPR) system. Classified as a distinct IP right under TRIPS, GIs are essentially considered to be private rights. This to an extent belies the unique nature of a GI as discussed in Chap. ļ»æļ»æļ»æļ»æ2 and it is widely argued that classification as a private IP right does not account for the characteristics of a GI that is based on public good considerations and collective ownership.

References

  • Barjolle D, Sylvander B (2000) PDO and PGI products: market, supply chains and institutions. Final report: FAIR 1 ā€“ CT 95 ā€“ 0306 June, European Commission, Brussels

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Barjolle D, Sylvander B (2002) Some factors of success for ā€œorigin labelled productsā€ in agro-food supply chains in Europe: market, internal resources and institutions. Ɖconomies et SociĆ©tĆ©s 25(9ā€“10):1441

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Barjolle D, RĆ©viron S, Sylvander B (2007) Creation et distribution de valeur economique dans les filieres de fromages AOP. Economies et Societes, serie Systemes agroalimentaires, Paris, AG no. 29, 9/2007

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Belletti G, Marescotti A (2011) Origin products, GI special protection schemes and rural development. In: Barham E, Sylvander B (eds) Labels of origin for food. Local development, global recognition. CABI International, Cambridge, ppĀ 75ā€“91

    ChapterĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Bowen S (2010) Development from within? The potential for geographical indications in the global South. J World Intellect Prop 13(2):231ā€“252

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Bramley C, Kirsten JF (2007) Exploring the economic rationale for protecting geographical indications in agriculture. Agrekon 46(1):69ā€“93

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Buchanan JM (1965) An economic theory of clubs. Economica 32:1

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Chappuis JM, Sans P (2000) Actors coordination: governance structures and institutions in supply chains of protected designation of origin. In: Sylvander B, Barjolle D, Arfini F (eds) The socio-Ā­economics of origin labelled products in agro-food supply chains: spatial, institutional and co-ordination aspects. Series Actes et Communications, 17(1). INRA, Paris

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Cornes R, Sandler T (1996) The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    BookĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Giovannucci D, Josling T, Kerr W, Oā€™Connor B, Yeung MT (2009) Guide to geographical indications: linking products and their origins. International Trade Centre (ITC), Geneva. http://www.intracen.org/publications/. Accessed 9 Nov 2012

  • Gopalakrishnan NS, Nair PS, Babu AK (2007) Exploring the relationship between geographical indications and traditional knowledge: an analysis of the legal tools for the protection of geographical indications in Asia. ICTSD working paper, August 2007, Geneva, Switzerland

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hinrichs C (2003) The practice and politics of food system localization. J Rural Stud 19(1):33ā€“45

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Hughes J (2009) Coffee and chocolate: can we help developing country farmers through geographical indications? Report prepared for the International Intellectual Property Institute, Washington, DC

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Ilbery B, Kneafsey M (2000) Registering regional speciality food and drink products in the United Kingdom: the case of PDOs and PGIs. Area 32(3):317ā€“325

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Jain S (2009) Effects of the extension of geographical indications: a South Asian perspective. Asia-Pac Dev J 16(2)

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Jena PR, Grote U (2010) Changing institutions to protect regional heritage: a case for geographical indications in the Indian agrifood sector. Dev Policy Rev 28(2):217ā€“236

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Josling T (2006) The War on terroir: geographical indications as a transatlantic trade conflict. J Agric Econ 57(3):337ā€“363

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Kaplinsky R, Fitter R (2001) Who gains from product rents as the coffee market becomes more differentiated? A value chain analysis. Institute of Development Studies (IDS) working paper 32(3), University of Sussex, UK

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Marette S (2005) The collective-quality promotion in the agribusiness sector: an overview (2005) Working paper 05-WP406. Centre for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Maskus HE (2003) Observations on the development potential of geographical indications. Paper prepared for the UN millennium project task force on trade

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Moran W (1993) Rural space as intellectual property. Pol Geogr 12:263ā€“277

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Moschini G, Menepace L, Pick D (2008) Geographical indications and the provision of quality in agricultural markets. Am J Agric Econ 90(3):794ā€“812

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Pacciani A, Belletti G, Marescotti A, Scaramuzzi S (2001) The role of typical products in fostering rural development and the effects of regulation (EEC) 2081/92. In: 73rd seminar of the European Association of Agricultural Economists, Ancona, 28ā€“30 June

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • RĆ©viron S, ThĆ©venod-Mottet E, EL Benni N (2009) Geographical indications: creation and distribution of economic value in developing countries, NCCR working paper no 14. World Trade Institute, Bern, Switzerland

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Thiedig F, Sylvander B (2000) Welcome to the club? An economical approach to geographical indications in the European Union. Agrarwirtschaft 49:428

    Google ScholarĀ 

  • Torre A (2002) Les AOC sont-elles des clubs? RĆ©flexions sur les conditions de lā€™action collective localisĆ©e, entre coopĆ©ration et rĆØgles formelles. Revue dā€™Ć©conomie industrielle 100:39ā€“62

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  • Vlok JHJ, Euston-Brown DIW (2002) The patterns within, and the ecological processes that sustain the Subtropical Thicket Vegetation in the planning domain for the Subtropical Thicket Ecosystem Planning (STEP) Project. Report no. 40. Terrestrial Ecology Research Unit, University of Port Elizabeth, Port Elizabeth

    Google ScholarĀ 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Estelle BiƩnabe .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

Ā© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

BiƩnabe, E., Jordaan, D., Bramley, C. (2013). Private Versus Public Quality Schemes for Origin-Labelled Products: Insights from the Karakul Pelts and Camdeboo Mohair Industries. In: Bramley, C., Bienabe, E., Kirsten, J. (eds) Developing Geographical Indications in the South. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6748-5_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics