Skip to main content

Buybacks to Restore the Southern Murray-Darling Basin

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Modeling of Water

Part of the book series: Global Issues in Water Policy ((GLOB,volume 3))

Abstract

We use TERM-H2O in analysing the effects of the Australian Government buying back water from irrigators in the Southern Murray-Darling Basin (SMDB) and thereby increasing river flows. Results are explained using data from the model and simplified theory. We refer to this as the ‘back-of-the-envelope’ approach. Back-of-the-envelope calculations and regressions allow us to explain key features of the results including differences in regional outcomes. Controversially, our results suggest that buyback would increase economic activity in SMDB. Although a scheme of environmentally useful size would sharply increase the price of irrigation water, there would be little effect on aggregate SMDB farm output. Instead, farm resources would be reallocated between activities. Because farmers are owners of water rights, they would benefit from the price increase induced by buyback. Community anxiety in the basin over buybacks may have arisen because the buyback process started during a period of drought-induced stress.

This chapter reproduces with permission substantial portions of Dixon et al. (2011).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We use a version of the model that identifies 19 regions (13 in SMDB) and 35 industries (17 farm industries).

  2. 2.

    This scheme is hypothetical but seemed realistic at the time we completed our modeling. PC (2010, p. 261) refers to a 1,500-GL buyback as being the benchmark used by COAG. Subsequently, with the return of heavy rains in 2010–11, both the size of the buyback mentioned in public discussions (MDBA 2010) and estimates of the likely availability of irrigation water without the buyback have been revised upwards. The 1,500-GL scenario reported in this chapter is based on 2005–06, allocations. This represents a similar percentage of water removed from irrigation as 3,000 GL across the basin (north plus south) based on entitlements.

  3. 3.

    −0.30  =  1/(−8.63  +  3.83*1.37) and −0.13  =  1/(−8.63  +  3.83*0.23).

  4. 4.

    This is consistent with the meta-analysis of water price elasticities by Scheierling et al. (2006).

  5. 5.

    In assessing these implied elasticity values, it is necessary to consider the definition of irrigation water. On our definition, about 30% of irrigation water is obtained by irrigators directly from rain falling on their land. Our elasticities can be converted into elasticities of demand for diverted water by dividing by 0.7, giving a range from −0.18 to −0.42. This range is compatible with the value −0.3 quoted in a recent ABARE study (Hone et al. 2010, p. 30) in which demand elasticities refer to diverted water.

  6. 6.

    Table 6.1 includes only 15 of the 17 farm industries mentioned in Chap. 5. It excludes the two sugar industries that have negligible output in the SMDB.

  7. 7.

    Water costs were computed using baseline water prices (Fig. 6.3) even for water supplied under a free allocation or by rainfall.

  8. 8.

    In terms of conventional econometrics, (6.12) is impressive. Potentially, it is fitted with 1,950 observations (= 15 industries by 13 regions by 10 years). In fact, we used only 1,753 observations because we excluded cells with zero production. The t-statistics on our three variables are large (over 30). However, we have not reported them here because we do not think they have a valid interpretation. Our equation is not derived from a sample of outcomes from a stochastic process. It is a summary of a set of results produced by a non-stochastic piece of arithmetic, the solution of a CGE model.

  9. 9.

    We assume that farmers in SMDB consume each year 5% of the amount that they receive from the government for their permanent water rights. This turns out in the long run to be similar to a situation in which farmers sell their water each year to the government at the average price applying in that year and, for consumption purposes, treat their water revenue as current income.

  10. 10.

    We assume normal GDP growth of 3% a year. This means that GDP grows by 0.0059% every 17 h.

  11. 11.

    Prolonged drought worsened the environmental crisis in the Coorong and lower lakes. Senator Xenophon agreed to support a stimulus package devised by the then Rudd government in exchange for a short-term commitment of $500 million for buybacks (Keane 2009).

  12. 12.

    One of our motivations for using a dynamic CGE model to estimate the impacts of buyback is that baseline conditions influence policy impacts. No factor varies as much in scarcity as water, reflected in both irrigation water availability and dryland productivity. Therefore, the interaction between drought and the buyback process may be important in analysis of the economic impacts of buyback.

  13. 13.

    Government initiatives that established irrigation schemes did not involve market signals. Other objectives were at play, including soldier settlement schemes after both of the world wars. There is an almost universal tendency among irrigation schemes towards over-allocation in the absence of market signals.

  14. 14.

    This trend is based on offer prices provided by the Australian Government throughout 2010: changes in expectations lagged the breaking of the drought by a year or so: http://www.environment.gov.au/water/policy-programs/entitlement-purchasing/average-prices.html.

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Glyn Wittwer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Calculating the Price of a Permanent Right to a Unit of Irrigation Water in the Southern Murray-Darling Basin

Appendix: Calculating the Price of a Permanent Right to a Unit of Irrigation Water in the Southern Murray-Darling Basin

We calculate the price [PPerR(t)] that a farmer would need to receive in year t (t  =  2009, …, 2016) to induce him/her to give up the permanent right to an annual allocation of one unit of irrigation water according to:

$$\text{PPerR}\left(\text{t}\right)={\displaystyle \sum _{\text{y}=\text{t}}^{\infty }\frac{\text{E}[\text{P}(\text{y})]*\text{E}[\text{S}(\text{y})]}{{(1+\text{d})}^{\text{y}-\text{t}}}}\text{}\text{t}=2009,\dots,2016$$
(6.14)

where

  • E indicates expectation

  • P(y) is the price of water in year y

  • d is the discount rate (assumed to be 0.08 reflecting 3% inflation and a 5% real rate of interest)

  • S(y) is the share of water rights in year y that is in fact allocated

As mentioned in Sect. 6.2, the S(y)s in 2009, 2010 and 2011 were assumed to be 0.7, 0.8 and 0.9, reflecting drought conditions that have made delivery of full water allocations impossible. For 2012–18, we set S(y) at one.

We assume that the expected values for P(y) and S(y) are given as follows:

$$\text{E}[\text{P}(\text{y})]=\text{PS}(\text{y}),\text{}\text{y}=2009,\dots,2018$$
(6.15)
$$ \text{E}[\text{S}(\text{y})]=\text{S}(\text{y}),\text{}\text{y}=2009,\dots,2018 $$
(6.16)
$$\text{E}[\text{P}(\text{y})]=\text{PS}(2018)*{1.03}^{\text{y}-2018}*\text{SF}(\text{y})\text{}\text{y}>2018 $$
(6.17)
$$\begin{array}{l}\rm{E}[\rm{S}(\rm{y})]=\rm{S}(\rm{t})\rm{y}>2018,\rm{ t}\in \left\{2009,\dots,2018\right\}\\rm{and}\\ \rm{}\rm{y}=\rm{t}+10*\rm{n for n a positive integer}\end{array}$$
(6.18)

and

$$\text{SF}\left(\text{y}\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{ll}1\hfill &\text{if}\text{E}\left[\text{S}\left(\text{y}\right)\right]=1\hfill \\ 1.4\hfill &\text{if}\text{E}\left[\text{S}\left(\text{y}\right)\right]=0.9\hfill \\ 1.84\hfill &\text{if}\text{E}\left[\text{S}\left(\text{y}\right)\right]=0.8\hfill \\ 2.4\hfill &\text{if}\text{E}\left[\text{S}\left(\text{y}\right)\right]=0.7\hfill \end{array}\right.$$
(6.19)

Via (6.15), we set expectations for water prices in 2009–18 according to the simulated values [PS(y)] obtained in our policy simulation, that is, with the buyback scheme in place. Via (6.16), we set the expected allocation shares in 2009–2018 according to the values adopted in our simulation. Via (6.17), we allow for 3% inflation in the determination of expected water prices for years beyond 2018. We also introduce a scarcity factor [SF(y)] to reflect periodic droughts. As shown in (6.19), in years in which the expected allocation share is less than one, the scarcity factor magnifies the expected price of water. The magnifications (1.4, 1.84 and 2.4) were calculated via simulations showing the effects on prices of reduced allocations. Via (6.18), we assume that the pattern of droughts (and hence allocation shares) in the decades beyond 2018 repeats the pattern assumed for the decade from 2009 to 2018.

Prices in 2009, dollars per ML calculated from (6.14) to (6.19), are shown in Table 6.2. They imply an average price between 2009 and 2016 of $2,081. The average price per ML for sales of permanent water rights in SMDB up until 31 January 2010 was $1,654 on sales of 502 GL (the average annual equivalent of 796 GL of entitlements; see PC (2010, Table 1.2)). A somewhat higher price could be expected if the Commonwealth implemented a buyback scheme totalling 1,500 GL as assumed in this paper. The Howard plan included a provision of $3 billion for buybacks (Australian Government 2007). Given the prices in Table 6.2, the total cost of the 1,500-GL program is $3.1 billion.

Table 6.2 Prices of permanent water rights ($ per ML, 2009 prices)

The expected frequency of future droughts is likely to be higher when the basin remains in drought and then fall after the drought ends. Available data indicate that the asset price of water fell in 2010.Footnote 14 That the price only fell more than a year after the drought had broken indicates that market players remained cautious for a time before changing their expectations. The calculated costs to the Australian Government of the scenario analysed in this chapter would have fallen had the assumed frequency of future droughts fallen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media B.V.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dixon, P.B., Rimmer, M.T., Wittwer, G. (2012). Buybacks to Restore the Southern Murray-Darling Basin. In: Wittwer, G. (eds) Economic Modeling of Water. Global Issues in Water Policy, vol 3. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-2876-9_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics