Skip to main content

Randomness, Financial Markets and the Brownian Motion: A Reflection on the Role of Mathematics in Their Interaction with Financial Theory After 1973

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
EPSA Philosophical Issues in the Sciences
  • 547 Accesses

Abstract

This article provides a brief overview of the construction of mathematical finance and suggests some questions of philosophy of science raised by the study of this field.

Remarks and comments on this paper are welcome and may be addressesd to the author at: ghislaine.idabouk@gmail.com.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Section 13.4 of this paper, we will also consider the paper by Robert C. Merton (Merton 1973) as a founding article of Mathematical Finance.

  2. 2.

    I consider here, as is standard among finance academics, that “Modern Financial Theory” emerged after the publication of Harry Markowitz’s paper (Markowitz 1952). This boundary date with previous financial theory might be questioned. Yet, it is beyond the scope of this paper, which addresses mathematical finance after 1973, to do so.

  3. 3.

    See http://www.cboe.com/AboutCBOE/History.aspx

  4. 4.

    In this article, the analysis is restricted to a limited corpus of academic articles identified in Sections 13.4 and 13.5, which I consider as a first, coherent building block of mathematical finance. The latter has then evolved into several directions to extend the Black and Scholes model (stochastic volatility, jump-diffusion processes) and to address issues of asset pricing in incomplete markets. The analysis of these extensions from a philosophy of science standpoint is left for future research.

  5. 5.

    Fama’s PhD dissertation was published in the January 1965 issue of the Journal of Business (see Fama 1965).

  6. 6.

    See Belze and Spieser (2005, p 198).

  7. 7.

    See Belze and Spieser (2005, p 241).

  8. 8.

    A portfolio is a combination of financial instruments. The weight of each asset in the portfolio is given in proportion of the total value of the portfolio.

  9. 9.

    The CAPM was developed independently by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1969) and Mossin (1966), and also by Jack Treynor, but in an unpublished memorandum (1961).

  10. 10.

    This can formally be written as \(\forall i,E\left ({r}_{i}\right ) = {r}_{f} + {\beta }_{i}\left (E\left ({r}_{M}\right ) - {r}_{f}\right )\), where r i is the return of the i-th asset, r M is the return of the market portfolio, r f is the risk-free rate and \(\forall i,{\beta }_{i} = \frac{\mathrm{cov}\left ({r}_{i},{r}_{M}\right )} {V \left ({r}_{M}\right )}\).

  11. 11.

    Modigliani and Miller are not the inventors of the notion of arbitrage. It is already present in the works of Irving Fisher. Yet Modigliani and Miller’s paper contributed to spreading the use of arbitrage reasoning among financial economists.

  12. 12.

    Efficiency here is informational efficiency.

  13. 13.

    Although several attempts at option pricing were made, before 1973, by some economists including the father figure of the MIT Economics Department, Paul Samuelson (see Sprenkle 1961; Ayres 1963; Boness 1964; Samuelson 1965; Baumol et al. 1966; Chen 1970).

  14. 14.

    Mehrling claims though that the early reasons of Black’s interest in option pricing are unknown.

  15. 15.

    A stochastic process is a collection of random variables.

  16. 16.

    The Brownian motion is a particular stochastic process. It starts at 0 at time 0, has independent and stationary increments (if we consider that the filtration is the natural one), and the increments follow a centered normal distribution with a variance proportional to the time interval.

  17. 17.

    Although Black acknowledges Merton’s contribution for the arbitrage approach.

  18. 18.

    Black and Scholes do not justify their intuition. They seem to be reasoning as in traditional differential calculus, which in this case is a reasoning error. Yet, the intuition was correct and it can be properly proved using stochastic differential calculus.

  19. 19.

    Black and Scholes reason in terms of null Beta (CAPM influence throughout).

  20. 20.

    I used Black and Scholes’ notations here. w 1 is the partial derivative of the option price with respect to the stock price.

  21. 21.

    Value here simply means number of units multiplied by price.

  22. 22.

    Here, Black and Scholes implicitly use the assumption that the portfolio is “self-financing”, a notion which will be introduced later in Mathematical Finance. Otherwise their computation would be wrong.

  23. 23.

    An arbitrage opportunity is the possibility to make a profit with no cost and no risk.

  24. 24.

    Merton and Scholes were awarded the Alfred Nobel Memorial Prize the same year for their “new method to determine the value of derivatives” (Black, who died in 1995, could not receive it as it is not awarded posthumously).

  25. 25.

    Initially, “rational option pricing” for Merton is simply such that no asset is dominant nor dominated. Obviously this definition being too generic, he then had to restrict it to be able to get a price for options.

  26. 26.

    Anyways Black and Scholes were neither the first ones to use the Brownian motion (and not even the geometric Brownian motion) nor the first ones to use continuous time modeling in Financial Economics.

  27. 27.

    Mostly Brownian motion in this first phase, though not exclusively. The study here is restricted to papers with Brownian motion models, see also footnote 5.

References

  • Ayres HF (1963) Risk aversion in the warrants market. Indus Manag Rev 4:497–505

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Malkiel BG, Quandt RE (1966) The valuation of convertible securities. Quart J Econ 80:48–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belze L, Spieser P (2005) Histoire de la Finance. Le temps, le calcul et les promesses. Vuibert, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Black F (1976) The pricing of commodity contracts. J Financ Econ 3:167–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Pol Econ 81:637–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boness J (1964) Elements of a theory of stock-option values. J Pol Econ 72:163–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen A (1970) A model of warrant pricing in a dynamic market. J Financ 25:1041–1060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF (1965) The behavior of stock market prices. J Business 38:34–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF (1970) Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. J Financ 25:383–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1907) The rate of interest. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) The theory of interest. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Garman MB, Kohlhagen SW (1983) Foreign currency options values. J Int Money Financ 2:231–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham B, Dodd DL (1934) Security analysis. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison JM, Kreps DM (1979) Martingales and arbitrage in multperiod securities markets. J Econ Theory 20:381–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison JM, Pliska SR (1981) Martingales and stochastic integrals on the theory of continuous trading. Stochast Proces Appl 11:215–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps DM (1981) Arbitrage and equilibrium in economies with infinitely many commodities. J Math Econ 8:15–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lintner J (1965) The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Rev of Econ and Stat 47(1):13–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie D, Millo Y (2003) Construction d’un marché et performation théorique. Sociologie historique d’une bourse de produits dérivés financiers. Réseaux 122:15–61

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie D, Muniesa F, Siu L (2007) Do economists make markets? Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Margrabe W (1978) The value of an option to exchange one asset for another. J Financ 33:177–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz HM (1952) Portfolio selection. J Financ 7:77–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz HM (1959) Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling P (2005) Fischer black and the revolutionary idea of finance. Wiley, Hoboken, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1973) Theory of rational option pricing. Bell J Econ Manage Sci 4(1):141–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC, Samuelson PA (1969) A complete model of warrant pricing that maximizes utility. Indus Manag Rev 10:17–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller M (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Review 48(3):261–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossin J (1966) Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34:768–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1965) Rational theory of warrant pricing. Indus Manag Rev 6:13–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Financ 19:425–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Sprenkle C (1961) Warrant prices as indications of expectations. Yale Econ Essays 1:179–232

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin J (1958) Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. Rev Econ Stud 25:65–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treynor J (1961) Market value, time and risk. Treynor papers

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams JB (1938) The theory of investment value. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Science+Business Media B.V.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Idabouk, G. (2010). Randomness, Financial Markets and the Brownian Motion: A Reflection on the Role of Mathematics in Their Interaction with Financial Theory After 1973. In: Suárez, M., Dorato, M., Rédei, M. (eds) EPSA Philosophical Issues in the Sciences. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-90-481-3252-2_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics