Skip to main content

Diffusion of Defaults Among Financial Institutions

  • Chapter
Econophysics of Systemic Risk and Network Dynamics

Part of the book series: New Economic Windows ((NEW))

  • 1965 Accesses

Abstract

The paper proposes a simple unified model for the diffusion of defaults across financial institutions and presents some measures for evaluating the risk imposed by a bank on the system. So far the standard contagion processes might not incorporate some important features of financial contagion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the following, a \(\tilde{~}\) on variable a means that the variable is random.

  2. 2.

    In a model with partial default as in [6], Cifuentes et al. [4] introduce a different mechanism in which the non-defaulting banks have to sell in order to satisfy some solvability ratio constraints.

  3. 3.

    Eisenberg and Noe [6] introduce a model in which default can be partial, represented by a default level on liabilities. For a measure of the threat index of a bank in that model, see Demange [5].

  4. 4.

    The process fits in the class of linear ‘threshold’ models as introduced by Granovetter [9]. More precisely, the linear model assumes a uniform distribution on the threshold, here the \(\tilde{{\mathbf{ z}}}\), and an influence of j on i, here ω ji . A node not yet ‘active’ at step t becomes active in step t if the influence of its neighbors in step t−1 is larger than its threshold, here if the sum of their liabilities, ∑ j∈D ω ji to i is larger than the threshold z i .

  5. 5.

    For closed sets C and C′ and i not in C∩C′, surely z i ≥V i (C) or z i ≥V i (C′). Since both V i (C) and V i (C′) are larger or equal to V i (C∩C′), z i ≥V i (C∩C′): C∩C′ is closed.

  6. 6.

    This assumes that the cost only depends on the set D and not on the precise values of z.

  7. 7.

    Here the expression is similar to some measures of ‘power’ or ‘prestige’ developed in sociology such as the Katz prestige index [11].

  8. 8.

    [14] also consider the loss imposed by a bank to each subsystem and derives the contribution to risk of that bank by taking an average (the Shapley value).

  9. 9.

    Consider for example the problem of finding a subset A that maximizes Φ(A) under some constraints, say the cardinality of A less than a number m. Under sub-modularity, a fast algorithm provides an approximation for the problem. The algorithm is called ‘greedy’: it first looks for i with the largest value for Φ among the singletons, say i 1 that maximizes Φ({i}), then for j with the largest incremental change over i 1, say i 2 that maximizes Φ({i,i 1})−Φ({i 1}), and so on m times. The exact problem is known to be NP-hard in the size of n.

  10. 10.

    Intuitively, there should be a link between the sub-modularity or super-modularity of L and the properties of the diffusion process itself, in particular the distribution of \({D}(\tilde{z})\) given A. Sub-modularity of L suggests a non-explosive dynamics of contagion. However I do not know of any result of this kind.

  11. 11.

    What matters is the correlation that is unknown at the time of the evaluation.

  12. 12.

    The condition is satisfied if there is a chance for the bank to default alone. This occurs for example if its initial values of the capital and liabilities are set so that a Value at Risk requirement is just binding. Specifically, given a level α, say 99 %, the level of capital, e i , and the interbank assets and liabilities are set so that the probability of default is equal to the level 1−α: F i (v i )=1−α. But VaR does not make much sense in a context with a uniform distribution.

  13. 13.

    Most standard distributions have a log-concave density. Then the ratio \(\frac{F(x+\delta)-F(x)}{1-F(x)}\), related to the hazard rate (see for example Bergstrom and Bagnoli [3]) is increasing. Though this is compatible with the concavity of F, this suggests that concavity is far from being guaranteed.

References

  1. Adrian T, Brunnermeier MK (2011) CoVaR. NBER Working Paper No. 17457

    Google Scholar 

  2. Allen F, Gale D (2000) Financial contagion. J Polit Econ 108(1):1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Bergstrom T, Bagnoli M (2005) Log-concave probability and its applications. Econ Theory 26:445–469

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Cifuentes R, Ferrucci G, Shin HS (2004) Liquidity risk and contagion. J Eur Econ Assoc 3(2–3):556–566

    Google Scholar 

  5. Demange G (2012) Contagion in financial networks: a threat index. PSE WP 2012-02. http://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00662513

  6. Eisenberg L, Noe TH (2001) Systemic risk in financial systems. Manag Sci 47(2):236–249

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Elsinger H, Lehar A, Summer M (2006) Risk assessment for banking systems. Manag Sci 52(9):1301–1314

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Freixas X, Parigi BM, Rochet J-C (2000) Systemic risk, interbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank. J Money Credit Bank 32(3):611–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Granovetter M (1978) Threshold models of collective behavior. Am J Sociol 83(6):1420–1443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Gai P, Kapadia S (2010) Contagion in financial networks. Proc R Soc A 466(2120):2401–2423

    Article  MathSciNet  ADS  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Katz L (1953) A new status index derived from sociometric analysis. Psychometrika 18(1):39–43

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. Kempe D, Kleinberg J, Tardos É (2003) Maximizing the spread of influence through a social network. In: Proceedings of the ninth ACM SIGKDD international conference on knowledge discovery and data mining (KDD ’03). ACM, New York, USA, pp 137–146. doi:10.1145/956750.956769

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  13. Mossel E, Roch S (2007) On the submodularity of influence in social networks. In: Proceedings of the thirty-ninth annual ACM symposium on theory of computing (STOC ’07). ACM, New York, USA, pp 128–134. doi:10.1145/1250790.1250811

    Google Scholar 

  14. Tarashev NA, Borio CEV, Tsatsaronis K (2010) Attributing systemic risk to individual institutions. BIS Working Paper No. 308. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1631761

  15. Upper C (2011) Simulation methods to assess the danger of contagion in interbank markets. J Financ Stab 7:111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Yuan Zhang for research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabrielle Demange .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Italia

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Demange, G. (2013). Diffusion of Defaults Among Financial Institutions. In: Abergel, F., Chakrabarti, B., Chakraborti, A., Ghosh, A. (eds) Econophysics of Systemic Risk and Network Dynamics. New Economic Windows. Springer, Milano. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-88-470-2553-0_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics