Skip to main content

Abstract

In this section we explore three main obstacles to the development of an effective and coherent innovation policy in the European Union: the saga of the EU patent, the problems faced by technology and knowledge/transfer legislation, and EU standardization policy. We find that in these areas, despite a long-standing debate and several attempts to converge on more socially desirable outcomes, a lot still needs to be done before the European Union will be able to count on effective and efficient legal rules and institutions that could serve as catalysts for breakthroughs in research and innovation in the EU27.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 69.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The main international instrument is the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property, of 20 March 1883, revised several times.

  2. 2.

    The Convention on the Grant of European Patents of 5 October 1973 as amended by the act revising Article 63 EPC of 17 December 1991 and by decisions of the Administrative Council of the European Patent Organization of 21 December 1978, 13 December 1994, 20 October 1995, 5 December 1996, 10 December 1998 and 27 October 2005, further amended by the London Agreement in 2000.

  3. 3.

    The European patent can be granted for up to 38 contracting states.

  4. 4.

    The European Parliament of Enterprises (Eurochambres) debated and voted “that the absence of a Community patent harms European business” on 14 October 2008.

  5. 5.

    The goal to obtain a Community patent while improving the existing systems was declared by the EC in [24, p. 7].

  6. 6.

    An increase in the number of patents is considered a plague that reveals the anticommons problem, generating huge transaction costs, reducing incentives to innovation and undermining the very innovative process that intellectual property rights should foster. See the traditional contribution of Heller and Eisenberg [51].

  7. 7.

    It is not by chance that the European Commission has raised the issue of access to the patent system for SMEs within the Small Business Act [28, p. 13].

  8. 8.

    As the WIPO noted, “the costs of protection may be perceived by many SMEs as exceeding the potential benefits to be obtained from protection, particularly considering that a significant part of the costs may be incurred before the product has reached the market” [112, p. 7].

  9. 9.

    Data are made available by the EC in [25, p. 2].

  10. 10.

    The map is available at http://www.worldmapper.org. For useful data on the production of patents in the USA, see [111] and [103].

  11. 11.

    As a matter of fact, a small number of patents is kept alive until the very last moment. At some point in time, the cost of renewal outweighs the advantages deriving from sales of patented items.

  12. 12.

    See [34]. A detailed account of costs and potential savings by a Community patent system can be read in [19]. See also data provided in the Annex I in [25, p. 17].

  13. 13.

    To further the position of patent applicants in the USA, the USPTO has proposed in 2010 a change in the patent law that would effectively allow a 12-month extension to the provisional application period. In this way, applicants would be given additional time to determine whether patent protection should be pursued and would enjoy a deferment in the payment of fees.

  14. 14.

    The full name is ‘Agreement on the Application of Article 65 of the Convention on the Grant of European Patents’.

  15. 15.

    Two cases are often taken as an example of inconsistent results: the Sara Lee/Phillips Electronics case and the Document Security Systems v. European Central Bank case, where the rulings of judges differed across member states.

  16. 16.

    Important papers and contributions have been produced on this topic. For instance, see [93] (“Patent quality is the capacity of a granted patent to meet (or exceed) the statutory standards of patentability - most importantly, to be novel, non-obvious, and clearly and sufficiently described.”).

  17. 17.

    There is a conspicuous body of literature and policy studies to support this statement. See, e.g., [38]. A signal of alarm on the situation of the USPTO came from Judge Paul Michel [80].

  18. 18.

    Maskus [77] warned about the risks of a patent policy based on a “the more the better” approach at the cost of lower quality.

  19. 19.

    After a number of years of public and congressional debate, on 16 September 2011, the Congress of the United States enacted the Public Law 112–29, Leahy-Smith America Invents Act, introducing significant changes in the patent system that aim to modernise it and ensure higher quality of patents and fairness in the procedure. For comments see [101].

  20. 20.

    This feature of patent litigation has produced serious problems for patent owners, due to the so-called torpedo.

  21. 21.

    Lanjouw and Shankerman [63] have demonstrated that individuals and small firms in the USA can be at a significant disadvantage in protection of their patent rights because of the small size of their portfolios. See also [71].

  22. 22.

    Notably, a post-grant opposition procedure is available at the EPO but not in the USA, where validity actions fall immediately under the jurisdiction of the civil (federal) courts.

  23. 23.

    As the Union replaced the Community, the “Community” patent became the “unitary” patent. Of course, the use of “European” was precluded to avoid confusion with the title granted by the European Patent Office under the EPC.

  24. 24.

    This study estimates that an integrated patent litigation system would generate savings of €148 – 289 million by 2013.

  25. 25.

    Patent policy is part of the European Union’s broader consideration of intellectual property rights in general. Many of the features of a high-quality, balanced, consistent and affordable patent system are desirable for all other forms of exclusivity and this point has been made clear in [27, p. 5].

  26. 26.

    This is a typical situation of obstacles created to law reform processes by incumbent groups opposing the challenge of competition in a wider scenario. For a description of counteractions to the competition of legal systems see [88, p. 411].

  27. 27.

    According to [19, p. 32], the business sector (including SMEs) would earn €250 million, and the EPO and NPOs €43 and 78 million, respectively. Net financial flows for patent agents and translators would amount to €-270 million and €-121 million for lawyers. “In other words, nearly €400 million would be redirected from patent attorneys, translators and lawyers to patent offices and the business sector” [109, p. 5].

  28. 28.

    As recalled in [27, p. 10], as far as SMEs are concerned, the Small Business Act also sets out, as one qualifying action, the encouragement to SMEs to benefit more from opportunities offered by the internal market and its systems of intellectual property protection. If the patent system is not adequate, the encouragement is useless.

  29. 29.

    See [94]. Interesting data, as far as the US market is concerned, are provided by [46, p. 1318].

  30. 30.

    Law and economics literature has explained that costs related to patent protection trigger a comparison with alternative forms of protection, including trade secrecy. See, among others, [41] and [89].

  31. 31.

    Already in 2007, Pro Ton Europe – the European Network of Technology Transfer Offices in Public Research Organizations – advocated the reduction of filing and maintenance fees for universities, as happens in the USA (Pro Ton Europe, Brussels, 31 August 2007).

  32. 32.

    A clear policy proposal is made by Van Pottelsberghe [109, p. 7] to reduce fees for SMEs and YICs.

  33. 33.

    Differences in procedures could make the outcome of litigation highly unpredictable.

  34. 34.

    One form of support could be financial to cover costs of litigation or to buy insurance policies for patent litigation, a kind of product that has low diffusion and high costs.

  35. 35.

    See data provided for the European Commission in [91, p. 11].

  36. 36.

    The IP5 Group includes patent offices from Europe (EPO), US (USPTO), Japan (JPO), Korea (KIPO) and China (SIPO). It works on ten work-packages, each one led by one of the offices.

  37. 37.

    Indeed, in the USA data and policy studies support the assumption about the link between an efficient, cost-effective, high-quality patent system and economic growth. See [94].

  38. 38.

    Interestingly, the Commission is considering using the legal basis of article 118 for the creation of an optional “unitary” copyright title (see [34, p. 11]). The unitary effect is thus becoming a surrogate for federal titles that cannot be created otherwise.

  39. 39.

    Decision 2011/167/EU, in O.J. March 22, 2011 L 76/53.

  40. 40.

    The appeal was filed before the Court of Justice on 31 May 2011.

  41. 41.

    More specifically, see articles 142 EPC, 45 PCT and 19 of the Paris Convention.

  42. 42.

    This argument about the unfair advantage that the tri-lingual system would cause for countries other than France and Germany has been used to oppose the enhanced cooperation and to criticise the project. It appears weak if one considers how its effects can be mitigated with a system of reimbursements and to some extent is the necessary step to a unitary patent system that relies on the existing European Patent Organization, rather than starting from scratch.

  43. 43.

    For costs, see Section 3.2.5. Estimates of savings are available in [25, p. 8].

  44. 44.

    See Court of Justice of the European Union, 8 March 2011, Avis 1/09.

  45. 45.

    The reference is clearly to the Brussels system, including the Brussels Convention of 1968, the Brussels I Regulation and the Lugano Convention.

  46. 46.

    An initial reference to the Fifth Freedom is in [27, p. 3].

  47. 47.

    For the definition, see Section 1.3.4.

  48. 48.

    This was also a point made by President Barroso in his speech at the European Innovation Summit, European Parliament, Brussels, 13 October 2009.

  49. 49.

    The European Commission has repeatedly suggested that innovation should not be considered only as a technical fact (see, for instance, [31, par. 3.3]). Under a truly holistic view innovation is abroad concept that embraces also services, the environment, the educational system and energy policy.

  50. 50.

    Official data are taken from the Green Paper [36, p. 3]. An even more impressive picture of resources available under EU-funded programs is available in Chapter 2.

  51. 51.

    See Chapter 1 for discussion about possible policy routes.

  52. 52.

    This point is extremely clear in [31, p. 9].

  53. 53.

    The last disappointing example was the approach of the conference in Copenhagen. A few days after the conference closed, there was silence on the issue of climate change.

  54. 54.

    There is a problem of discriminating technologies by denying protection, since under the TRIPs Agreement discrimination is not allowed. On access to pharmaceuticals for countries poor in manufacturing capabilities, see [55, p. 28].

  55. 55.

    An empirical study conducted by Hall and Helmers [49] seems to reinforce the idea of mixed business models for CRTs, based on both exclusivity and open innovation.

  56. 56.

    The idea was first developed by Cohen and Levinthal [16] and in its original formulation refers to such organisations as research teams of firms, but it can be easily applied to states.

  57. 57.

    A structured proposal is offered by the Alliance for Clean Technology Innovation (ACTI), a group of leading companies, including 3M, Air Liquide, Alstom, ExxonMobil, General Electric, Microsoft, Philips, Siemens and Vestas. The proposal for the creation of technology centres is provided in a concept paper titled “Climate Change Technology Centers”, 2 October 2009.

  58. 58.

    For a discussion of patent quality as a crucial policy issue, see Section 3.4.5.

  59. 59.

    The Licensing Executives Society (LES) periodically administers a survey to its members to assess the development of markets for technology and to highlight the most relevant impediments that are still in place.

  60. 60.

    eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, L.L.C., 547 U.S. 388 (2006).

  61. 61.

    See Section 3.11.

  62. 62.

    Although very volatile, there is a difference between non-practicing and non-manufacturing entities, since manufacturing refers to the production whereas practicing is meant as any form of use of the technology (including manufacturing). The difference can be more easily grasped when considering research centres, which are technically non-manufacturing entities, even though they cannot be treated as pure patent-holding entities, since doing research is a way to practise. Most notably, universities are nonmanufacturing institutions, and yet they cannot be considered non-practising entities.

  63. 63.

    Whereas an ambush is often referred to as an act rather than the entity that practises it, the latter is often assimilated to a “troll”. There are multiple bibliographic references on SSOs, patent ambushes, FRAND and RAND commitments. For a description of the role of SSOs in the modern patent system, see [65]. For the problem of hold-ups in the standard setting context, see also [18]. Contrast with [22]. See also [66] and [95].

  64. 64.

    After the decision in Bilski v. Kappos, 130 S. Ct. 3218 (2010), the future ofbusiness method patents in the USA seems to be facing a serious obstacle.

  65. 65.

    For a complete review, see the highly documented report of the OECD [87].

  66. 66.

    For definitions, see SEC Release No. 34–37619 (29/8/1996), 186; CESR (2002), Standards for Alternative Trading Systems (“CESR ATS Standards”), CESR/02-086b, July.

  67. 67.

    The Italian solution is of particular interest, as the ministry requires the use of a specific rating tool to assess the credit merit of the firm that applies for funding under the Fondo Nazionale per l’Innovazione (FNI).

  68. 68.

    One of the authors of this book is a member of the IPR Expert Group appointed by the DG Enterprise of the European Commission. The view herein expressed can be referred exclusively to the authors

  69. 69.

    For a complete review, see [86, p. 30–39].

  70. 70.

    See Section 3.6.

  71. 71.

    In [28, p. 15] the European Commission noted that only around three out of ten SMEs in Europe indicated that in 2007 they had introduced new products or generated revenues from new products. This is clearly evidence of the difficulties smaller firms encounter in managing innovation due also to a lack of expertise, as well as of human and financial resources.

  72. 72.

    The Italian platform for rating patents is now currently being expanded and adapted for design.

  73. 73.

    The European Commission has also been concerned with guiding firms and institutions with the measurement of intangible capital. See the Report [99].

  74. 74.

    According to the definition proposed by the European Commission, standards are voluntary documents that define technical or quality requirements with which current or future products, production processes, services or method may comply; see [35].

  75. 75.

    See, for a detailed description, [20].

  76. 76.

    See [20, p. 12]. The same study quotes earlier surveys such as that conducted by the German Occupational Safety and Health committee, which found that 35% of SMEs had no idea of sources from which to find information about standards. Also NORMAPME reported that finding information about standards - including whether a given standard is still in place - is among the most difficult issues for SMEs. In addition, SMEs also have difficulties in understanding the context of the standard, such as the references to other standards, etc.

  77. 77.

    See [37]. The Expert Panel for the Review of the European Standardization System (EXPRESS) comprised 30 individual experts from European, national and international standards organisations, industry, SMEs, NGOs, trade unions, academia, fora and consortia, and public authorities from EU member States and EFTA countries.

  78. 78.

    Importantly, the rapid definition of a standard can be a factor that supports the process of transferring results of research projects to the market. This is the reason why, to some extent, the definition of standard is seen more and more as a process that must run parallel with R&D.

  79. 79.

    We acknowledge Sisvel for the data, which were initially presented at one of the meetings of the CEPS Task Force on innovation

  80. 80.

    The position of the Commission can be read in [35].

  81. 81.

    The proposal for an amendment to the Regulation on European Standardization was introduced on 1 June 2011.

References

  1. Amihud Y, Mendelson H, Pedersen LH (2005) Liquidity and asset prices. Found Trends Finance 1:269–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Anand BN, Khanna T (2000) The structure of licensing contracts. J Ind Econ 48:103–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Arora A, Ceccagnoli M (2006) Patent protection, complementary assets, and firm’s incentives for technology licensing. Manag Sci 52:293–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Arora A, Fosfuri A (2003) Licensing the market for technology. J Econ Behav Organ 52:277–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Arora A, Merges RP (2004) Specialized supply firms, property rights and firm boundaries. Ind Corporate Change 13:451–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Arora A, Fosfuri A, Gambardella A (2001) Markets for technology: the economics of innovation and corporate strategy. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  7. Athreye S, Cantwell J (2007) Creating competition? Globalization and the emergence of new technology producers. Res Policy 36:209–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Benassi M, Di Minin A (2009) Playing in between: patent brokers in markets for technology. R&D Manag 39:68–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Bessen J (2003) Patent thickets: strategic patenting of complex technologies. http://ssrn.com/abstract=327760

  10. CEPS Task Force Report (2010) A new approach to innovation policy in the European Union. CEPS, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  11. Cesaroni F (2004) Technological outsourcing and product diversification: do markets for technology affect firms’ strategies? Res Policy 33:1547–1564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Chesbrough H (2003) Open innovation. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  13. Chien CV (2010) From arms race to marketplace: the complex patent ecosystem and its implications for the patent system. http://www.worldmapper.org

  14. Choi JP (2002) A dynamic analysis of licensing: the “boomerang” effect and grant-back clauses. Int Econ Rev 43:803–829

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Cockburn IM (2007) Is the market for technology working? Obstacles to licensing inventions, and ways to licensing inventions, and ways to reduce them. Paper presented at the Conference on Economics of Technology Policy, Monte Verità, Ascona, 17–22 June 2007

    Google Scholar 

  16. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Admin Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Copenhagen Economics and The IPR Company (2009) Are IPR a barrier to the transfer of climate change technology? Copenhagen

    Google Scholar 

  18. Cotter T (2008) Patent holdup, patent remedies, and antitrust responses. Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper No. 08-39

    Google Scholar 

  19. Danguy J, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B (2009) Cost-benefit analysis of the Community patent, Bruegel Working Paper 08/2009

    Google Scholar 

  20. De Vries H, Blind K, Mangelsdorf A, Verheul H, Van der Zwan J (2009) SME access to European Standardization. Enabling small and medium-sized enterprises to achieve greater benefit from standards and from involvement in standardization. Rotterdam School of Management. ftp://ftp.cen.eu/cen/Services/SMEs/SME%20Web/SME% 20Access%20Report.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  21. Domowitz I (2002) Liquidity, transaction costs, and reintermediation in electronic markets. J Finan Serv Res 22:141–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Elhauge E (2008) Do patent holdup and royalty stacking lead to systematically excessive royalties? http://ssrn.com/abstract=1139133

  23. EPO (European Patent Office) (2007) Scenarios for the future. www.epo.org/topics/ patentsystem/scenarios-for-the-future.html

    Google Scholar 

  24. European Commission (2005) More research and innovation — investing for growth and employment: a common approach, COM(2005) 448 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  25. European Commission (2007) Enhancing the Patent System in Europe, COM(2007) 165 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  26. European Commission 2007 Improving knowledge transfer between research institutions and industry across Europe: embracing open innovation. Implementing the Lisbon Agenda, COM(2007) 182. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  27. European Commission (2008) An industrial property rights strategy for Europe, COM(2008) 465/3. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  28. European Commission (2008) A “Small Business Act” for Europe, COM(2008) 394 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  29. European Commission (2008) Recommendation on the management of intellectual property in knowledge transfer activities and Code of Practice for universities and other public research organizations, COM(2008) 1329. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  30. European Commission (2009) Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry, Final report, Staff Working Paper, Part I. http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/pharmaceuticals/inquiry/staffworkingpaperpart1.pdf

  31. European Commission (2010) Europe 2020 Flagship Initiative Innovation Union, COM(2010) 546 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  32. European Commission (2010) Proposal for a Council decision authorising enhanced cooperation in the area of the creation of unitary patent protection, COM(2010) 790 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  33. European Commission (2011) A resource-efficient Europe: flagship initiative under the Europe 2020 Strategy, COM(2011) 21 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  34. European Commission (2011) A single market for intellectual property rights, COM (2011) 287 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  35. European Commission (2011) A strategic vision for European standards: moving forward to enhance and accelerate the sustainable growth of the European economy by 2020, COM (2011) 311 final. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  36. European Commission (2011) From challenges to opportunities: towards a common strategic framework for EU research and innovation funding, COM(2011) 48. Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  37. Expert Panel for the Review of the European Standardization System (2010) Standardization for a competitive and innovative Europe: a vision for 2020, available at http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/european-standards/files/express/exp384expressreportfinaldistriben.pdf

  38. Federal Trade Commission (2003) To promote innovation: the proper balance of competition and the patent law and policy. https://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf

  39. Feldman M, Feller I, Bercovitz J, Burton R (2002) Equity and the technology transfer strategies of American research universities. Manag Sci 48:105–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Fischer T, Henkel J (2009) Patent trolls on markets for technology: an empirical analysis of trolls’ patent acquisitions. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1523102

  41. Friedman DD, Landes WM, Posner RA (1991) Some economics of trade secret law. J Econ Perspect 5:61–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Gallini NT (2002) The economics of patents: lessons from recent U.S. patent reform. J Econ Perspect 16:131–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Gans JS, Stern S (2003) The product market and the market for “ideas”: commercialization strategies for technology entrepreneurs. Res Policy 32:333–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Garman MB (1976) Market microstructure. J Financ Econ 3:257–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Graham SJH, Harhoff D (2006) Can post-grant reviews improve patent system design? A twin study of US and European patents. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5680

    Google Scholar 

  46. Graham SJH, Merges RP, Samuelson P, Sichelman T (2010) High technology entrepreneurs and the patent system: results of the 2008 Berkeley Patent Survey. Berkeley Technol Law J 24:1255–1328

    Google Scholar 

  47. Green J, Scotchmer S (1990) Novelty and disclosure in patent law. RAND J Econ 21:131–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Grindley PC, Teece DJ (1997) Managing intellectual capital: licensing and crosslicensing in semiconductors and electronics. Calif Manag Rev 39:8–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Hall BH, Helmers C (2011) Innovation and diffusion of clean/green technology: can patent commons help? NBER Working Paper No. 16920

    Google Scholar 

  50. Harhoff D, Hall BH, Von Graevenitz G, Hoisl K, Wagner S (2007) The strategic use of patents and its implications for enterprise and competition policies, Final Report. http://www.en.inno-tec.bwl.uni-uenchen.de/research/proj/laufendeprojekte/patents/stratpat2007.pdf

  51. Heller MA, Eisenberg RS (1998) Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research. Science 280:698–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Henderson P, Pierantozzi M (2008) Increasing transparency in the IP transaction markets. Intellect Asset Manag 31

    Google Scholar 

  53. Hovenkamp H (2008) Patent Continuations, patent deception, and standard setting: the Rambus and Broadcom decisions. University of IOWA Legal Studies Research Paper No. 08-25

    Google Scholar 

  54. Hsu Y, Ziedonis RH (2007) Patents as quality signals for entrepreneurial ventures. Paper presented at the DRUID Summer Conference 2007, Copenhagen Business School, Copenhagen, 18–20 June 2007

    Google Scholar 

  55. International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) (2007) Current and emerging intellectual property issues for business. A roadmap for business and policy makers, 8th edn. ICC, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  56. Jensen R, Thursby M (2001) Proofs and prototypes for sale: the tale of university licensing. Am Econ Rev 91:240–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Japan Institute of Invention and Innovation (JIII) (2003) Survey on patent valuation system in patent licensing market. JIII, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  58. Kessel M, Hall S (2006) Avoiding premature licensing. Nat Rev Drug Discov 5:985–986

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Kim YJ, Vonortas NS (2006) Technology licensing partners. J Econ Bus 58:273–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  60. Kline D (2003) Sharing the corporate crown jewels. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 44:89–93

    Google Scholar 

  61. Knight D (2008) Cost of patent disputes. IAM Magazine: Patents in Europe 2008: 25–28

    Google Scholar 

  62. Kulatilaka N, Lin L (2006) Impact of licensing on investment and financing of technology development. Manag Sci 52:1824–1837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  63. Lanjouw JO, Shankerman M (2004) Protecting intellectual property rights: are small firms handicapped? J Law Econ 47:45–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Lee R (1998) What is an exchange? Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  65. Lemley M (2002) Intellectual property rights and standard-setting organizations. Boalt Working Papers in Public Law No. 24

    Google Scholar 

  66. Lemley M, Shapiro C (2007) Reply: Patent holdup and royalty stacking. Texas Law Rev 85:2163–2173

    Google Scholar 

  67. Leone JR, Berneman LP (2008) Revenue interest financing: a strategic alternative to accessing capital through licensing in the life sciences. Les Nouvelles (Dec)

    Google Scholar 

  68. Leone MI, Laursen K (2011) Patent exploitation strategies and value creation. In: Munari F, Oriani R (eds) The economic valuation of patents. Methods, application and cases. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 82–106

    Google Scholar 

  69. Leone MI, Oriani R (2009) Licensing as a source of financing. Paper presented at the 29th Annual International Conference of the Strategic Management Society, Washington, DC, 11–14 October 2009

    Google Scholar 

  70. Lerner J (1994) The importance of patent scope: an empirical analysis. RAND J Econ 25:319–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  71. Lerner J (1995) Patenting in the shadow of competitors. J Law Econ 38:463–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  72. Lewis T, Reichman JH (2003) Using liability rules to stimulate local innovations in developing countries: a law and economics primer. http://www.earthinstitute.columbia.edu/cgsd/documents/lewisreichman.pdf

  73. Lichtenthaler U, Ernst H (2007) Developing reputation to overcome the imperfections in the markets for knowledge. Res Policy 36:37–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  74. London Economics (2010) Patent backlogs and mutual recognition, Final Report to the Intellectual Property Office. London

    Google Scholar 

  75. Mann RJ, Sager TW (2007) Patents, venture capital and software start-ups. Res Policy 36:193–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  76. Mansfield E (1991) Academic research and industrial innovation. Res Policy 20:1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  77. Maskus KE (2006) Reforming U.S. patent policy. Council on Foreign Relations, CRS No. 19

    Google Scholar 

  78. Mendi P (2007) Trade in disembodied technology and total factor productivity in OECD countries. Res Policy 36:121–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  79. Merges PR (1998) Property rights, transactions, and the value of intangible assets. University of California at Berkeley, School of Law (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  80. Michel P (2011) Fellow citizens: be on guard. J Patent Trademark Office Soc. http://www.jptos.org/chief-judge-paul-michel-speech.html

  81. Monk AHB (2009) The emerging market for intellectual property: drivers, restrainers, and implications. J Econ Geography 9:469–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  82. Moore K (2005) Worthless patents. George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 04-29

    Google Scholar 

  83. Morgan K (2004) The exaggerated death of geography: learning, proximity and territorial innovation systems. J Econ Geography 4:3–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  84. Munari F, Odasso C, Toschi L (2010) Patent-backed finance. In: Munari F, Oriani R (eds) The economic valuation of patents. Methods, application and cases. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 337–357

    Google Scholar 

  85. Munari F, Toschi L (2008) How good are VCs at valuing technology? An analysis of patenting and VC investments in nanotechnology. Paper presented at the Academy of Management, Anaheim, CA, 8–13 August 2008

    Google Scholar 

  86. OECD (2006) Valuation and exploitation of intellectual property. OECD STI Working Paper 2006/5

    Google Scholar 

  87. OECD (2009) The emerging patent marketplace. OECD STI Working Paper 2009/9

    Google Scholar 

  88. Ogus A (1999) Competition between national legal systems: a contribution of economic analysis to comparative law. Int Comp Law Q 48:405–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  89. Ordover JA (1991) A patent system for both diffusion and exclusion. J Econ Perspect 5:43–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  90. Pagano M (1989) Trading volume and asset liquidity. Q J Econ 104:25–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  91. PATQUAL (2011) Study on the quality of the patent system in Europe. PATQUAL, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  92. Pitkethly R (2001) Intellectual property strategy in Japanese and UK companies: patent licensing decisions and learning opportunities. Res Policy 30:425–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  93. Polk Wagner R (2009) Understanding patent quality mechanism. Univ Pa Law Rev 157:2135–2173

    Google Scholar 

  94. Rai A, Graham S, Doms M (2011) Patent reform. Unleashing innovation, promoting economic growth & producing high-paying jobs. White Paper from the U.S. Department of Commerce. Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  95. Rato M, Geradin D (2007) Can standard-setting lead to exploitative abuse? A dissonant view on patent hold-up, royalty stacking and the meaning of FRAND. Eur Competition J 3:101–107

    Google Scholar 

  96. Razgaitis R (2004) U.S./Canadian licensing in 2003: survey results. J Licensing Exec Soc 39:139–151

    Google Scholar 

  97. Reitzig M (2006) Valuing patents and patent portfolios from a corporate perspective: theoretical considerations, applied needs and future challenges. In: Bosworth D, Webster E (eds) The management of intellectual property. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  98. Reitzig M, Henkel J, Schneider F (2009) Collateral damage for R&D manufacturers: how patent sharks operate in markets for technology. Ind Corp Change 19:947–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  99. RICARDIS (2006) Reporting intellectual capital to augment research, development and innovation in SMEs. RICARDIS, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  100. Rivette K, Kline D (2000) Discovering new value in intellectual property. Harvard Bus Rev 55–66

    Google Scholar 

  101. Shacht WS, Thomas JR (2011) The Leahy-Smith America Invents Act: innovation issues. CRS Report for Congress, Congressional Research Service, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  102. Shapiro C (2001) Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard-setting. Innov Policy Econ 1:119–150

    Google Scholar 

  103. Shapiro RJ, Pham ND (2007) Economic effects of intellectual property-intensive manufacturing in the United States, a report for World Growth, available at http://www.sonecon.com/docs/studies/0807thevalueofip.pdf

  104. Stern P (2005) The role of intermediaries in technology transfer. Paper presented at the EPO-OECD-BMWA International Conference on Intellectual Property as an Economic Asset: Key Issues in Valuation and Exploitation, Berlin, 30 June–1 July 2005

    Google Scholar 

  105. Stoll HR (1992) Principles of trading market structure. J Financ Serv Res 6:75–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  106. Teece D J (1988) Capturing value from technological innovation: integration, strategic partnering, and licensing decisions. Strat Manag 18:46–61

    Google Scholar 

  107. The Patent Prospector (2007) available at http://www.patenthawk.com/blog/about.html

  108. Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B (2010) Europe should stop taxing innovation. Bruegel Policy Brief, Bruegel

    Google Scholar 

  109. Van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie B, Van Zeebroeck N (2008) Filing strategies and patent value. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP6821

    Google Scholar 

  110. Vattenfall Institute and McKinsey (2007) Global cost curve of GHG abatement opportunities beyond business as usual by 2030. McKinsey & Company

    Google Scholar 

  111. Wadhwa V, Rissing B, Chopra A, Balasubramanian R, Freilich A (2007) US-based global intellectual property creation. Kauffman Foundation

    Google Scholar 

  112. World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) (2003) Intellectual property (IP) rights and innovation in small and medium-sized enterprises. WIPO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  113. Wolfers J, Zitzewitz E (2004) Prediction markets. J Econ Perspect 18:107–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Italia

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Granieri, M., Renda, A. (2012). Key policies. In: Innovation Law and Policy in the European Union. Sxi — Springer for Innovation / Sxi — Springer per l’Innovazione. Springer, Milano. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-88-470-1917-1_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics