Skip to main content

Finance and Credit in a Model of Monetary Policy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Monetary Policy in India
  • 839 Accesses

Abstract

The question facing many emerging economies is the extent to which a workhorse advanced economy model can yield important insights for monetary policymaking. We note that the standard sticky price, monopolistically competitive model does not allow analysis of money and credit dynamics and led to a concentration of research on simple interest rate reaction functions. Time-varying financial frictions tend to act as a tax on intermediation activities and so can vary output in a significant manner. In this paper, we consider the implications of financial frictions for baseline monetary policy using a model calibrated on Indian data and find that a simple interest rate reaction function may not be welfare maximizing.

We are grateful for helpful conversations and comments from Philip Arestis, Chetan Ghate, Mike Joyce, Ken Kletzer, Jack Meaning, James Warren and participants at the BIS-OECD Workshop Panel on Policy Interaction: Fiscal Policy, Monetary Policy and Debt Interaction, the Reserve Bank of India. We also thanks Luisa Corrado, Germana Corrado, Sean Holly, Philip Tuner, Alex Waters and Fabrizio Zampolli for permission to draw on joint work. Any remaining errors are our own.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Chadha and Holly (2011) for a treatment of a number of partial equilibrium and general equilibrium modeling approaches that try to understand nonconventional monetary policies. Although there is a growing literature, a workhorse model has not yet been developed.

  2. 2.

    The call for more work on the monetary-financial nexus was made by Hammond et al. (2009). This paper forms part of an answer.

  3. 3.

    See Khan and Thomas (2014) on this important point. Note that if some markets are segmented financially then policy may have work harder to influence or act on those markets on which it has some (limited) influence.

  4. 4.

    The agenda involves writing down general equilibrium models built from the principles of household optimization that match key stylised facts of the business cycle behavior. The model can then be solved under various forms of stabilization policies under which the welfare of the household can be assessed and in which the Lucas critique is respected. Gabriel et al. (2012, 2016) support the need to include financial frictions in their estimated DSGE models of first a closed and then an open economy.

  5. 5.

    In 1925 prior to making the decision to return to an overvalued gold standard, Churchill had called for industry to be more content and finance less proud. By 2007, finance, it seemed to many, had it all.

  6. 6.

    With the development of many new credit instruments and the increasing levels of leverage of financial institutions, it seemed that markets were being completed.

  7. 7.

    Ironically at the same time, many of the price rigidities were being nicely ironed out by an explosion in production from China.

  8. 8.

    In Chadha et al. (2013b), we show how money and financial factors were excluded by design from having any amplification impact in the standard model.

  9. 9.

    See Mohanty and Rishabh (2016) in this volume for an analysis of open economy issues facing emerging economies. We maintain that the key issue is always the scale and cost of the supply of loanable funds whether from local sources or from abroad.

  10. 10.

    See IMF Article IV consultations (e.g. 2015) on the Indian monetary policy problem.

  11. 11.

    In our model developed in detail later we can assess (i) and (ii) but elsewhere we have studied (ii) and (iv).

  12. 12.

    In the model have two types of frictions in the investment decision. First, loans for investment are subject to a costly production function and secondly we also have some costs in the actual investment function. Both are required to have consumption and investment co-move positively.

  13. 13.

    The discussion in this section follows closely that of Breedon et al. (2012).

  14. 14.

    See Chadha et al. (2013b) for the implications for US bond yields from supply effects.

  15. 15.

    In practice, most major economies have a minimum level of required reserves relative to depositis. Our long-run target for India is set at 20 %.

  16. 16.

    The equations for the steady-state equations are listed in the technical appendix.

  17. 17.

    The steady state of the transfer level, the Lagrangian of the production constraint and base money depend on the above parameters. The steady state of the marginal cost is \(mc=\frac{\epsilon -1}{\epsilon }\).

  18. 18.

    Some authors have also described it as a measure of credit conditions within the economy. The rationale for this seems plausible as when credit conditions are tight, banks will require more collateral and will employ more monitoring work to provide the same amount of loans to the economy.

  19. 19.

    http://www.slideshare.net/iimjobs/india-banking-sector-report-april-2014 from Reserve Bank of India (2014).

  20. 20.

    The other four shock IRFs are available on request.

  21. 21.

    The additive nature of our household’s utility function allows us to take a Taylor expansion of each term and substitute it back into the original function. The labor demand function is then rearranged for monitoring work, a second-order expansion taken and substitution made. This process is then repeated for the marginal cost equation. Following Galí (2008) we substitute the resulting linear term in goods sector employment for a second-order term in inflation using the sales equal net production constraint.

  22. 22.

    A referee suggested rightly that we rerun these calculations for different choices of deep parameters, but we have undertaken this kind of analysis elsewhere using advanced country calibrations and obtained qualitatively similar results.

  23. 23.

    We do though need more work to help those financially excluded to benefit from financial intermediation, see Chakravarty and Pal (2013).

  24. 24.

    See Caglar et al. (2011) for a summary and papers by Harrison (2011) as well as Gertler and Karadi (2011) for the baseline papers. Also see Kim and Aum (2011) for results on the Korean economy.

  25. 25.

    The RBI published some of its views in 2015 in a roadmap report to which our paper can be thought to be complementary.

References

  • Banerjee, S., & Basu, P. (2016). Effect of quantitative easing on the indian economy: a DSGE perspective, in this volume.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel III (2010). International framework for liquidity risk measurement, standards and monitoring. http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs188.htm.

  • Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In: J. B. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (1 ed., Vol. 1, Chapter 21, pp. 1341–1393).

    Google Scholar 

  • Breedon, F., Chadha, J. S., & Waters, A. (2012). The financial market impact of UK quantitative easing. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28(4), 702–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caglar, E., Chadha, J. S., Meaning, J., Warren, J., & Waters, A. (2011). Central bank balance sheet policies: three views from the DSGE literature. Interest rates, prices and liquidity (pp. 240–273). Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris, C. W., M. Larrain, M. Liberti, & Sturgess, J. (2015). How collateral laws shape lending and sectoral activity. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., & Holly, S. (2011). Interest rates, prices and liquidity. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., & Warren, J. (2012). Accounting for the great recession in the UK: Real business cycles and financial frictions. The Manchester School, 18(S4), 43–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., Corrado, L., & Holly, S. (2013a). A note on money and the conduct of monetary policy. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 18(08), 1854–1883.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., Corrado, L., & Meaning, J. (2012). Reserves, liquidity and money: an assessment of balance sheet policies. In: Bank for International Settlements (ed.), Are central bank balance sheets in Asia too large? (Vol. 66, pp. 294–347). Bank for International Settlements.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J., Turner, P., & Zampolli, F. (2013b). The Ties that Bind: Monetary Policy and Government Debt Management, Oxford Review of Economic Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., Corrado, L., & Sun, Q. (2010). Money and liquidity effects: Separating demand from supply. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34(9), 1732–1747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chadha, J. S., & Corrado, L. (2012). Macro-prudential policy on liquidity: What does a DSGE model tell us? Journal of Economics and Business, 64(1), 37–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakraborty, S., & Otsu, K. (2013). Business cycle accounting of the BRIC economies. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 13(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty, S. R., & Pal, R. (2013). Financial inclusion in india: An axiomatic approach. Journal of Policy Modelling, 35, 813–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V. V., Kehoe, P. J., & McGrattan, E. R. (2007). Business cycle accounting. Econometrica, 75(3), 781–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel, V., Levine, P., & Yang, B. (2016). An estimated DSGE open-economy model of the indian economy with financial frictions, in this volume.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel, V., Levine, P., Pearlman, J., & Yang, B. (2012). An estimated DSGE model of the indian economy. Chapter 29 in Ghate (2012).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D. (1982). Money in equilibrium. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J. (2008). Monetary policy. Inflation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework, Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., & Karadi, P. (2011). A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghate, C. (2012). The oxford handbook of the indian economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend, M., & McCallum, B. T. (2007). Banking and interest rates in monetary policy analysis: A quantitative exploration. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(5), 1480–1507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, A. (2014). Policy actions and outcomes. History of Monetary Policy in India since Independence: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. (2009). The’ high sensitivity of economic activity to financial frictions. NBER mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, G., Kanbur, R., & Prasad, E. S. (2009). Monetary policy challenges for emerging market economies, brookings global economy and development working paper 36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, R. (2011). Asset purchase policies and portfolio effects: a DSGE analysis. Chapter in Chadha and Holly (2011).

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (2015). Article IV Consultation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T. J., & Prescott, E. C. (2002). Great depressions of the twentieth century. Review of Economic Dynamics, 5(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan, A., & Thomas, J. (2014). Revisiting the tale of two interest rates with endogenous asset market segmentation. in press Review of Economic Dynamics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, H., & Aum, S. (2011). The role of money and banking in monetary policy: Does it matter quantitatively for the korean economy? Economic Analysis, 21(1), 45–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R. G., & Watson, M. W. (1998). The solution of singular linear difference systems under rational expectations. In International Economic Review, 39(4), Symposium on Forecasting and Empirical Methods in Macroeconomics and Finance (pp.1015–1026).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kletzer, K. (2014). Financial frictions and monetary policy transmission in India, Chapter 22 in Ghate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohanty, M. S., & Rishabh, K. (2016). Financial intermediation and monetary policy transmission in EMEs: what has changed post-2008 crisis?, in this volume.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reserve Bank of India. (2014). Report of the expert committee to revise and strengthen the monetary policy framework.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jagjit S. Chadha .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

7 Appendix

7 Appendix

1.1 7.1 First-Order Condition

1.1.1 7.1.1 Households and Banking Sector

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}:\frac{\phi }{c_{t}}-\lambda _{t}-\mu _{t}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(45)
$$\begin{aligned} B_{t+1}:\frac{\mu _{t}}{\lambda _{t}} \Omega _{t}-1+\beta E_{t}\left( \frac{\lambda _{t+1}}{\lambda _{t}}\frac{P_{t}}{ P_{t+1}}(1+R_{t}^{B})\right) =0 \end{aligned}$$
(46)
$$\begin{aligned} K_{t+1}:\frac{\mu _{t}}{\lambda _{t}} kA3_{t}q_{t}\Omega _{t}-q_{t}+\beta E_{t}\left( \frac{\lambda _{t+1}}{ \lambda _{t}}\frac{\xi _{t+1}}{\lambda _{t+1}}\eta \left( \frac{K_{t+1}}{ A1_{t+1}n_{t+1}}\right) ^{(\eta -1)}+\frac{\lambda _{t+1}}{\lambda _{t}} q_{t+1}(1-\delta )\right) =0 \end{aligned}$$
(47)

where \(\frac{\mu _{t}}{\lambda _{t}}=\frac{\phi }{c_{t}\lambda _{t}}-1\) measures households’ marginal utility relative to shadow value of funds. \( \Omega _{t}=\frac{\partial y_{t}}{\partial b_{t+1}}=\frac{\alpha y_{t}}{ b_{t+1}+A3_{t}kq_{t}K_{t+1}}\) is marginal value of bonds as collateral.

$$\begin{aligned} I_{t}:-\lambda _{t}+\lambda _{t}q_{t}(1-S(\frac{I_{t}}{ I_{t-1}})-S^{\prime }(\frac{I_{t}}{I_{t-1}})\frac{I_{t}}{I_{t-1}} )+\beta \lambda _{t+1}q_{t+1}S^{\prime }(\frac{I_{t+1}}{I_{t}})\left( \frac{ I_{t+1}}{I_{t}}\right) ^{2}-\mu _{t}=0 \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} n_{t}^{s},m_{t}^{s}:\frac{1-\phi }{ 1-n_{t}^{s}-m_{t}^{s}}=w_{t}\lambda _{t} \end{aligned}$$
(48)
$$\begin{aligned} m_{t}:w_{t}=\frac{\mu _{t}}{\lambda _{t}}(1-\alpha ) \frac{y_{t}}{m_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(49)

1.1.2 7.1.2 Firms (Wholesale Good Producing Firm and Retailer)

$$\begin{aligned} n_{t}:w_{t}=\frac{\xi _{t}}{\lambda _{t}}(1-\eta )\frac{ y_{t}}{n_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(50)
$$\begin{aligned} mc_{t}=\frac{\epsilon -1}{\epsilon }\frac{\xi _{t}}{\lambda _{t}} \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}^{f}:\sum _{s=0}^{\infty }\theta ^{s}E_{t}\left[ \Lambda _{t,s}Y_{t,t+s}\left( \frac{P_{t}^{f}}{P_{t-1}}-\mathrm { X_{\psi }mc_{t}\pi _{t-1,t+s}}\right) \right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(51)

where \(P_{t}^{f}\) is forward-looking firms’ optimal price (resetting price), \(\Lambda _{t,s}=\beta ^{s}\left( \frac{c_{t+s}}{c_{t}}\right) ^{-1}\left( \frac{ P_{t}}{P_{t+s}}\right) \) is the households’ stochastic discount factor, \( X_{\psi }=1/mc\) is desired markup. \(mc_{t}\) is real marginal cost, \( \pi _{t-1,t+s}=\frac{P_{t+s}}{P_{t-1}}\).

Aggregate price level is given by

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}:P_{t}=\theta P_{t-1}+(1-\theta )\bar{P}_{t}^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(52)

where \(\bar{P}_{t}^{*}\) is an index of prices set in period t based on the forward-looking and backward-looking price setting behavior such that

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{P}_{t}^{*}=\omega P_{t}^{b}+(1-\omega )P_{t}^{f} \end{aligned}$$
(53)

where \(P_{t}^{b}\) is the price set by the backward-looking rule of thumb (\( P_{t}^{b}=\bar{P}_{t-1}^{*}+\pi _{t-1}\)), \(P_{t}^{f}\) is the price set by forward-looking firms, and \(\omega \) is the degree of backward-lookingness and \(1-\omega \) is forward-lookingness.

Hybrid New Keynesian Philips Curve is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\pi }{}_{t}=\kappa \widehat{mc}_{t}+\gamma _{f}E_{t}(\widehat{\pi }{} _{t+1})+\gamma _{b}\widehat{\pi }{}_{t-1}+a5_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(54)

1.2 7.2 Market Clearing

Resource Constraint

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}=c_{t}+I_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Financial Market (Deposits)

$$\begin{aligned} D_{t}^{s}=D_{t}^{d}=\frac{P_{t}y_{t}}{v_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(56)

Balanced Government Budget

$$\begin{aligned} T_{t}=g_{t}-tax_{t}=\frac{B_{t+1}}{P_{t}(1+R_{t}^{B})}-\frac{B_{t}}{ P_{t}^{A} }-\frac{r_{t}}{P_{t}}R_{t}^{IB} \end{aligned}$$
(57)

1.3 7.3 Steady States

For the productivity and monitoring shocks we assume a trend growth rate equal to \(A2_{t}=A1_{t}=(1+\varrho )^{t}\). In steady state \(q=1\), \( A2=A1=(1+\varrho )\), \(\lambda \) shrinks at rate \(\varrho \) so \(\frac{ \lambda _{t+1}}{\lambda _{t}}=\frac{1}{1+\varrho }\). There is no inflation so \( P=1\) while capital grows at rate \(\varrho \) in steady state. We use the constant steady-state bonds to output (\(boy=\frac{\text{ B }}{(1+R^{B})y}\)). That is, we assume that the fiscal authority’s policy is set in order to stabilize \(boy_{t}\) at an exogenous policy-determined value.

1.3.1 7.3.1 The Core Steady States

The following 10 equations give the steady-state value for y, c, I, K, m, n, w, \(\lambda \), \(\mu \), \(\Omega \):

$$\begin{aligned} y=c+I \end{aligned}$$
(58)
$$\begin{aligned} 1=\frac{vF}{1-rr}\left( boy+\frac{kK}{y}\right) ^{\alpha }\left( \frac{m}{y} \right) ^{1-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(59)
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega =\frac{\alpha }{\left( boy+\frac{kK}{y}\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(60)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1-\phi }{1-n-m}=w\lambda \end{aligned}$$
(61)
$$\begin{aligned} w=\frac{\mu }{\lambda }\frac{(1-\alpha )y}{m} \end{aligned}$$
(62)
$$\begin{aligned} w=\frac{\epsilon -1}{\epsilon }(1-\eta )\left( \frac{K}{n(1+\varrho )} \right) ^{\eta } \end{aligned}$$
(63)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mu }{\lambda }k\Omega -1+\beta \left[ \frac{1-\delta }{1+\varrho }+\eta \frac{ \epsilon -1}{\epsilon }\left( \frac{K}{n(1+\varrho )}\right) ^{\eta -1}\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(64)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{mc}=\left( \frac{K}{y(1+\varrho )}\right) ^{\eta }\left( \frac{n}{y} \right) ^{(1-\eta )} \end{aligned}$$
(65)
$$\begin{aligned} I=\frac{\rho +\delta }{1+\varrho }K \end{aligned}$$
(66)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mu }{\lambda }=\frac{\phi }{c\lambda }-1 \end{aligned}$$
(67)

1.3.2 7.3.2 Other Variables

$$\begin{aligned} D=\frac{y}{v} \end{aligned}$$
(68)
$$\begin{aligned} r=rrD=rr\frac{y}{v} \end{aligned}$$
(69)
$$\begin{aligned} L=(1-rr)D=(1-rr)\frac{y}{v} \end{aligned}$$
(70)
$$\begin{aligned} T=g-tax=b-b(1+R^{B})-rR^{IB} \end{aligned}$$
(71)
$$\begin{aligned} b=boy\times y \end{aligned}$$
(72)
$$\begin{aligned} R^{T}-R^{B}=LSY^{B}&=\Omega \end{aligned}$$
(73)
$$\begin{aligned} LSY^{K}=k\times LSY^{K} \end{aligned}$$
(74)
$$\begin{aligned} EFP&=\frac{vmw}{(1-\alpha )(1-rr)y}=\frac{\mu }{\lambda }\frac{v}{(1-rr)} \end{aligned}$$
(75)
$$\begin{aligned} CEFP=(1-\alpha )\times EFP=\frac{vmw}{(1-rr)y}=(1-\alpha )\frac{\mu }{\lambda } \frac{v}{(1-rr)} \end{aligned}$$
(76)
$$\begin{aligned} \tau =R^{L}-R^{IB} \end{aligned}$$
(77)

Accordingly spreads between interest rates can be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} R^{T}&=\frac{1+\varrho }{\beta }-1 \end{aligned}$$
(78)
$$\begin{aligned} R&=R^{T}-EFP \end{aligned}$$
(79)
$$\begin{aligned} R^{L}&=R^{IB}+CEFP \end{aligned}$$
(80)
$$\begin{aligned} R^{B}&=R^{T}-LSY^{B} \end{aligned}$$
(81)
$$\begin{aligned} R^{D}&=R(1-rr) \end{aligned}$$
(82)

1.4 7.4 Log-linearization

Consumption

$$\begin{aligned} c_{t}=-c(\lambda \lambda _{t}+\mu \mu _{t}) \end{aligned}$$
(83)

Supply of labor

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}=\frac{n}{1-n-m}n_{t}+\frac{m}{1-n-m}m_{t}-\lambda _{t} \end{aligned}$$
(84)

Demand for labor in the goods sector

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}=mc_{t}+y_{t}-n_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(85)

Demand for monitoring work

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}=\mu _{t}-\lambda _{t}+y_{t}-m_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(86)

Broad liquidity problem

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}=v_{t}+rr_{t}+(1-\alpha )(a2_{t}+m_{t})+\alpha \left( \frac{b}{boy+kK} b_{t+1}+\frac{kK}{boy+kK}(a3_{t}+q_{t}+K_{t+1})\right) \end{aligned}$$

where \(boy=\frac{B}{P(1+R^{B})y}\) and \(b_{t+1}=\frac{B_{t+1}}{ P_{t}(1+R_{t}^{B})}=boy_{t}+y_{t} \)

Marginal value of bond as collateral

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{t}=\frac{kK}{boy+kK/y}(y_{t}-q_{t}-K_{t+1}-a3_{t})+\frac{b}{boy+kK/y} b_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(87)

Asset price

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-k\Omega \frac{\mu }{\lambda }\right) q_{t}=&\frac{\beta }{1+\varrho } \left( 1-\delta +\eta mc\left( \frac{K}{n(1+\varrho )}\right) ^{\eta -1} \right) (E_{t}\lambda _{t+1}-\lambda _{t}) \\&\quad +\frac{\beta }{1+\varrho }(1-\delta )E_{t}q_{t+1}+k\Omega \frac{\mu }{\lambda } (\mu _{t}-\lambda _{t}+\Omega _{t}+a3_{t}) \\&\qquad \, +\frac{\beta }{1+\varrho }\eta mc\left( \frac{K}{n(1+\varrho )} \right) ^{\eta -1}E_{t}\left( mc_{t+1}+(1-\eta )(n_{t+1}+a1_{t+1})\right) \end{aligned}$$

Deposit-in-advance constraint (DIA)

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t}+y_{t}=D_{t}+v_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(88)

production function

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}=\eta K_{t}+(1-\eta )(a1_{t}+n_{t}) \end{aligned}$$
(89)

Goods Market Clearing Condition

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}=\frac{c}{y}c_{t}+\frac{I}{y}I_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(90)

Law of Motion of Capital

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t+1}=\frac{1-\delta }{1+\varrho }K_{t}+\frac{\varrho +\delta }{1+\varrho }I_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(91)

Investment

$$\begin{aligned} q_{t}=(1+\varrho )^{2}s\left[ (I_{t}-I_{t-1})-\beta \left( E_{t}(I_{t+1})-I_{t} \right) \right] +\frac{\mu }{\lambda }\mu _{t} \end{aligned}$$
(92)

Inflation

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{t}=p_{t}-p_{t-1} \end{aligned}$$
(93)

Philips curve

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{t}=\gamma _{b}\pi _{t-1}+\gamma _{f}E_{t}(\pi _{t+1})+\kappa mc_{t}+a5_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(94)

Government Budget Constraint

$$\begin{aligned} TT_{t}=b\left( b_{t+1}-b_{t}-R^{B}(b_{t}+R_{t}^{B}) \right) -rR^{IB}(r_{t}+R_{t}^{IB}) \end{aligned}$$
(95)

Riskless Interest Rate (Benchmark Interest Rate)

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{T}=\lambda _{t}-E_{t}(\lambda _{t+1})+E_{t}(\pi _{t+1}) \end{aligned}$$
(96)

Liquidity Service Yield (\(LSY_{t}\))

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{T}-R_{t}^{B}=\mu _{t}-\lambda _{t}+\Omega _{t} \end{aligned}$$
(97)

External Finance Premium (\(EFP_{t}\))

$$\begin{aligned} EFP_{t}=v_{t}+w_{t}+m_{t}-y_{t}+rr_{t}=\mu _{t}-\lambda _{t}+v_{t}+rr_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(98)

Interbank Interest Rate (Policy Rate)

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{IB}=R_{t}^{T}-EFP_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(99)

Loan Interest Rate

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{L}=R_{t}^{IB}+(C)EFP_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(100)

Bond Interest Rate

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{B}=R_{t}^{T}-LSY_{t}^{B} \end{aligned}$$
(101)

Deposit Interest Rate

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}^{D}=R_{t}^{IB}-\frac{rr}{1-rr}rr_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(102)

Monetary Policy Rule (Taylor Rule)

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t}=\rho R_{t-1}+(1-\rho )(\phi _{\pi }\pi _{t}+\phi _{y}mc_{t}+\phi _{f}f_{t})+a4_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(103)

OMO Policy Rule (Fiscal Policy Rule)

$$\begin{aligned} boy_{t}=a6_{t}=\rho _{boy}boy_{t-1}+\epsilon _{t}^{boy} \end{aligned}$$
(104)

Velocity

$$\begin{aligned} v_{t}=a7_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(105)

Liquidity Preference

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _{t}=a8_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(106)

Endogenous Reserves

$$\begin{aligned} r_{t}=\frac{1}{rR^{T}}\left( R^{IB}R_{t}^{IB}-R^{L}R_{t}^{L}+\tau \tau _{t} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(107)

Loans

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}=D_{t}-\frac{1}{1-rr}rr_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(108)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Chadha, J.S., Kang, YK. (2016). Finance and Credit in a Model of Monetary Policy. In: Ghate, C., Kletzer, K. (eds) Monetary Policy in India. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2840-0_16

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2840-0_16

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New Delhi

  • Print ISBN: 978-81-322-2838-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-81-322-2840-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics