Skip to main content

An Estimated DSGE Open Economy Model of the Indian Economy with Financial Frictions

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Monetary Policy in India

Abstract

We develop an open economy DSGE model of the Indian economy and estimate it by Bayesian Maximum Likelihood methods. We build up in stages to a model with a number of features important for emerging economies in general and the Indian economy in particular: a large proportion of credit-constrained consumers, a financial accelerator facing domestic firms seeking to finance their investment, “liability dollarization” and incomplete exchange rate pass-through. Our estimation results support the inclusion of financial frictions in an otherwise standard small open economy model. The simulation properties of the estimated model are examined under a generalized inflation targeting Taylor-type interest rate rule with forward- and backward-looking components.

We acknowledge financial support for this research from the Foreign Commonwealth Office as a contribution to the project “Building Capacity and Consensus for Monetary and Financial Reform” led by the National Institute for Public Finance Policy (NIPFP). We also acknowledge constructive comments from an anonymous referee and Chetan Ghate. The paper has benefited from excellent research assistance provided by Rudrani Bhattachrya and Radhika Pandey, NIPFP.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In a parallel paper, Gabriel et al. (2012) focuses on a further important feature of emerging economies, informality, but only in a closed economy model.

  2. 2.

    Aggregate variables such as \(C_t\) and \(C_t^*\) are aggregates over varieties and in fact per capita measures. Relative total consumption in the two blocs is then given by \(\frac{\nu C_t}{(1-\nu ) C_t^*}\).

  3. 3.

    We do not attempt to endogenize the decision of firms to partially borrow foreign currency; this lies outside the scope of this paper.

  4. 4.

    The closed economy model with financial frictions is a special case when \(\varphi =1\).

  5. 5.

    Thus we can interpret \(\frac{1}{1-\xi _H }\) as the average duration for which prices are left unchanged..

  6. 6.

    Recall that we have imposed a symmetry condition \(\zeta =\zeta ^*\) at this point, i.e., the elasticity of substitution between differentiated goods produced in any one bloc is the same for consumers in both blocs.

  7. 7.

    Note that all aggregates, \(Y_t\), \(C_{H,t}\), etc., are expressed in per capita (household) terms.

  8. 8.

    The WPI rather than the CPI was officially used by the RBI until 2014 (i.e., at the time we produced the paper), mainly because it was the broader measure and there were four different CPI measures, depending on the type of worker.

  9. 9.

    The Bayesian system estimation techniques used in our study can easily handle variables measured with imprecision, by introducing stochastic measurement errors. Exploratory analysis revealed that measurement errors are a negligible source of uncertainty in our estimated models and we therefore focus on estimation results without measurement errors.

  10. 10.

    Employing the Hodrick–Prescott filter instead delivers time series with similar behavior and estimation results are qualitatively, and quantitatively, very close.

  11. 11.

    We chose not to calibrate \(\alpha \) to its steady-state value and instead freely estimate this parameter. The proximity of the estimated values for \(\alpha \) will provide additional indications regarding the quality of the fit for each model.

  12. 12.

    See Schorfheide (2000) for more details.

  13. 13.

    Mallick (2011) estimates a structural VAR with the exchange rate and provides evidence of exchange rate targeting by the RBI.

  14. 14.

    An alternative preference specification is the Jaimovich–Rebelo preferences (Jaimovich and Rebelo 2009), that allows for flexible parameterization of the strength of wealth effects on the labor supply decision. The preference takes the following form and habit evolves according to \(H_t=C_t^\kappa H_{t-1}^{1-\kappa }\). In the case with the wealth elasticity of labor supply \(\kappa =0\) there is no wealth effect on labor supply. This flexible specification links agents’ habits with their consumption decisions and can account for the high volatility of wage and consumption relative to output that characterizes developing countries. This feature may be important to study the effect of income on labor supply for emerging markets like India in adverse financial conditions: rising interest rate can induce larger short run wealth effects on labor supply despite of a significant drop in wages.

  15. 15.

    See Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), Chap. 9.

  16. 16.

    Thus we can interpret \(\frac{1}{1-\xi }\) as the average duration for which prices are left unchanged.

  17. 17.

    The same point applies to government debt when we introduce fiscal policy.

References

  • Adolfson, M., Laseen, S., Linde, J., & Villani, M. (2008). Evaluating an estimated new Keynesian small open economy model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32(8), 2690–2721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adrian, T., & Shin, H. S. (2009). Money, liquidity, and monetary policy. American Economic Review, 99(2), 600605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agenor, P., McDermott, C. J., & Prasad, E. S. (2000). Macroeconomic fluctuations in developing countries: Some stylized facts. The World Bank Economic Review, 14(2), 251–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, M., & Gopinath, G. (2007). Emerging market business cycles: The cycle is the trend. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 69–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrle, M. (2008). The role of trends and detrending in DGSE models. manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Economic growth (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batini, N., Gabriel, V., Levine, P., & Pearlman, J. (2010a). A floating versus managed exchange rate regime in a DSGE model of India. University of Surrey Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batini, N., Levine, P., & Pearlman, J. (2010b). Monetary Rules in Emerging Economies with Financial Market Imperfections. NBER Conference Volume, J. Gali & M. Gertler (Eds.), International dimensions of monetary policy. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benigno, P. (2001). Price stability with imperfect financial integration. CEPR Discussion Paper no. 2854.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The Financial Accelerator in Quantitative Business Cycles. In M. Woodford & J. B. Taylor (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1C). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, R., Patnaik, I., & Shah, A. (2010). Monetary policy with a weak transmission mechanism. Working Paper, National Institute for Public Finance and Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, P., & Gelman, A. (1998). General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 7(4), 434–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brozoza-Brzezina, M., Kolasa, M., & Makarski, K. (2013). The anatomy of standard DSGE models with financial frictions. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37, 32–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G., & Mishkin, F. S. (2003). The mirage of exchange rate regimes for emerging market countries. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(4), 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. A. (1998). Capital flows and capital-markets crises. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 1(1), 35–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlstrom, C. T., & Fuerst, T. S. (1997). Agency costs, net worth and business cycle fluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis. American Economic Review, 87, 893–910.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castillo, P., Montoro, C., & Tuesta, V. (2013). An estimated stochastic general equilibrium model with partial dollarization: A bayesian approach. Open Economies Review, 24 (217–165),

    Google Scholar 

  • Cespedes, L. F., Chang, R., & Velasco, A. (2004). Balance sheets and exchange rate policy. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1183–1193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chin, M., Filippeli, T., & Theodoridis, K. (2015). Cross-country co-movement in long-term interest rates: A DSGE approach. Staff Working Paper No. 530, Bank of England.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L. J., Trabandt, M., & Walentin, K. (2011). Introducing financial frictions and unemployment into a small open economy model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35(12), 19992041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, D. (2004). Monetary policy in emerging markets. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6), 1155–1181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cúrdia, V., & Woodford, M. (2010). Credit spreads and monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42, 3–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro, M., & Schorfheide, F. (2004). Priors from general equilibrium models for VARs. International Economic Review, 45, 643–673.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro, M., & Schorfheide, F. (2008). Forming priors for dsge models (and how it affects the assessment of nominal rigidities). Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(7), 11911208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro, M., Schorfheide, F., Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). On the fit of new keynesian models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 25(2), 123–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M. B., Lane, P. R., & Xu, J. (2006). Exchange rates and monetary policy in emerging market economies. The Economic Journal, 116(511), 478–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elekdag, S., Justiniano, A., & Tchakarov, I. (2005). An estimated small open economy model of the financial accelerator. IMF Discussion Paper No. WP/05/44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Villaverde, J. (2009). The econometrics of DSGE models. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Villaverde, J., & Rubio-Ramirez, J. F. (2004). Comparing dynamic equilibrium models to data: A Bayesian approach. Journal of Econometrics, 123, 153–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferroni, F. (2011). Trend agnostic one-step estimation of dsge models. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 11(1), 1690–1935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel, V., Levine, P., Pearlman, J., & Yang, B. (2012). An estimated model of the Indian economy. In C. Ghate (Ed.), Chapter in the “Handbook of the Indian Economy”. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel, V. J., Levine, P., & Spencer, C. (2009). How forward-looking is the fed? Direct estimates from a ‘Calvo-type’ rule. Economics Letters, 104(2), 92–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali, J. (2008). Monetary policy, inflation and the business cycle. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali, J., Lopez-Salido, J., & Valles, J. (2004). Rule-of-thumb consumers and the design of interest rate rules. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36(4), 739–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., & Karadi, P. (2011). A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1), 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., & Kiyotaki, N. (2012). Banking, liquidity and bank runs in an infinite horizon economy. Princeton University: Mimeo, NYU

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., & Natalucci, F.M. (2003). External constraints on monetary policy and the financial accelerator. NBER Working Paper No. 10128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (1999). Computational experiments and reality. University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iacoviello, M. (2005). House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review, 95(3), 739–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaimovich, N., & Rebelo, S. (2009). Can news about the future drive the business cycle? American Economic Review, 99(4), 10971118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, K., & J. P. and Vlieghe, G., (2004). House prices, consumption, and monetary policy: A financial accelerator approach. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(4), 414–435.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (2007). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin, A., Onatski, A., Williams, J.C., & Williams, N. (2006). Monetary policy under uncertainty in micro-founded macroeconomic models. In M. Gerler & K. Rogoff (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 2005 (pp. 229–387).

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, P., McAdam, P., & Pearlman, J. (2007). Inflation forecast rules and indeterminacy: A puzzle and a resolution. International Journal of Central Banking, 3, 77–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Litterman, R. B. (1983). A random walk, markov model for the distribution of time series. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics, 1(2), 169–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mallick, S. (2011). Macroeconomic shocks, monetary policy and implicit exchange rate targeting in india. Mimeo: Queen Mary University of London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F. S. (2006). The next great globalization: How disadvantaged nations can harness their financial systems to get rich. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumeyer, P. A., & Perri, F. (2005). Business cycles in emerging economies: The role of interest rates. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 345–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schorfheide, F. (2000). Loss function-based evaluation of DSGE models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15(6), 645–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shah, A. (2008). New issues in macroeconomic policy. NIPFP Working Paper No. 51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2003). An estimated stochastic dynamic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5), 1123–1175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review, 97(3), 586–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Virmani, V. (2004). Operationalising Taylor-type rules for the Indian economy: Issues and some results. Indian Institute of Management Ahmedabad Working Paper 2004-07-04.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul Levine .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

A    A Closed Economy Model

This section develops a standard New Keynesian (NK) DSGE model without any features we associate with emerging economies. To give us a preliminary insight into what is different about an emerging economy such as India. Every NK DSGE model has at its core a real business cycle model, describing the intertemporal problems facing consumers and firms and defining what would happen in the absence of the various Keynesian frictions. We first define a single-period utility for the representative agent in terms of consumption, \(C_t\), and leisure, \(L_t\), as

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _t= & {} \Lambda (C_{t}, L_t)= \frac{((C_{t}-h_CC_{t-1})^{(1-\varrho )}L_t^\varrho )^{1-\sigma }-1}{1-\sigma } \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

In this utility function \(\sigma \ge 1\) is a risk aversion parameter which is also the inverse of the intertemporal rate of substitution. \(h_C\) is a habit parameter for private consumption \(C_t\).Footnote 14 The parameter \(\varrho \in (0,1)\) defines the relative weight households place on consumption and this form of utility is compatible with a balanced growth steady state for for all \(\sigma \ge 1\).Footnote 15 For later use, we write down the marginal utilities of consumption and leisure as, respectively,

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{C,t}= & {} (1-\varrho ) (C_{t}-h_CC_{t-1})^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1} L_t^{\varrho (1-\sigma )} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{L,t}= & {} -\varrho (C_{t}-h_CC_{t-1})^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )} L_t^{\varrho (1-\sigma )-1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

The value function at time t of the representative household is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _t= E_t \left[ \sum _{s=0}^\infty \beta ^s \Lambda (C_{t+s}, L_{t+s}) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

where \(\beta \) is the discount factor. In a stochastic environment, the household’s problem at time t is to choose state-contingent plans for consumption \(\{C_t\}\), leisure, \(\{L_t\}\) and holdings of financial savings to maximize \(\Omega _t\) given its budget constraint in period t

$$\begin{aligned} B_{t+1}=B_t(1+R_t)+W_t h_t-C_t \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

where \(B_t\) is the net stock of real financial assets at the beginning of period t, \(W_t\) is the real wage rate, and \(R_t\) is the real interest rate paid on assets held at the beginning of period t. Hours worked are \(h_t=1-L_t\) and the total amount of time available for work or leisure is normalized at unity. Government spending is financed by lump-sum nondistortionary taxes throughout. The first-order conditions for this optimization problem are

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{C,t}= & {} \beta E_t\left[ (1+R_{t+1}) \Lambda _{C,t+1}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Lambda _{L,t}}{\Lambda _{C,t}}= & {} W_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

Equation (A.6) is the Euler consumption function: it equates the current marginal utility of consumption with the discounted marginal of consumption of a basket of goods in period \(t+1\) enhanced by the interest on savings. Thus, the household is indifferent as between consuming 1 unit of income today or \(1+R_{t+1}\) units in the next period. Equation (A.7) equates the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure with the real wage, the relative price of leisure. This completes the household component of the RBC model.

Turning to the production side, we assume that output \(Y_t\) is produced using hours, \(h_t\) and beginning-of-period capital \(K_t\) with a Cobb–Douglas production function

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}= & {} F(A_{t}, h_{t}, K_{t})=(A_{t} h_{t})^{\alpha } K_{t}^{1-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

where \(A_t\) is a technology parameter and \(Y_t\), \(h_t\), and \(K_t\) are all in per capita (household) units. Assume first that capital can adjust instantly without investment costs. Then equating the marginal product of labor with the real wage and the marginal product of capital with the cost of capital (given by the real interest rate plus the depreciation rate, \(R_t+\delta \)), we have

$$\begin{aligned} F_{h,t}= & {} \alpha \frac{Y_t}{h_t}=W_{t}\end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} F_{K,t}= & {} (1-\alpha ) \frac{Y_t}{K_t}=R_{t}+\delta \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)

Let investment in period t be \(I_t\). Then capital accumulates according to

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t+1}=(1-\delta ) K_t+I_t \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)

The RBC model is then completed with an output equilibrium equating supply and demand

$$\begin{aligned} Y_t=C_t+I_t+G_t \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

where \(G_t\) is government spending on services assumed to be formed out of the economy’s single good and by a financial market equilibrium. In this model, the only asset accumulated by households as a whole is capital, so the latter equilibrium is simply \(B_t=K_t\). Substituting into the household budget constraint (A.5) and using the first-order conditions (A.9) and (A.10), and (A.11) we end up with the output equilibrium condition (A.12). In other words, equilibrium in the two factor markets and the output market implies equilibrium in the remaining financial market, which is simply a statement of Walras’ Law.

Now let us introduce investment costs. It is convenient to introduce capital producing firms that at time t convert \(I_t\) of output into \((1-S(X_t))I_t\) of new capital sold at a real price \(Q_t\) and at a cost (that was absent before) of \(S(X_t)\). Here, \(X_t\equiv \frac{I_t}{I_{t-1}}\) and the function \(S(\cdot )\) satisfies \( S',\, S'' \ge 0\,;\,\,S(1+g)=S'(1+g)=0\). Thus, investment costs are convex and disappear along in the balanced growth steady state. They then maximize expected discounted profits

$$\begin{aligned} E_t \sum _{k=0}^\infty D_{t,t+k} \left[ Q_{t+k} (1-S\left( I_{t+k}/I_{t+k-1}\right) )I_{t+k} -I_{t+k} \right] \end{aligned}$$

where \(D_{t,t+k} \equiv \beta \frac{ \Lambda _{C,t+k}}{ \Lambda _{C,t}}\) is the real stochastic discount rate and

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t+1}= & {} (1-\delta ) K_t+(1-S(X_t))I_t \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)

This results in the first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} Q_t (1-S(X_t)-X_t S'(X_t))+E_t \left[ \frac{1}{(1+R_{t+1})}\, Q_{t+1} S'(X_{t+1}) \frac{I_{t+1}^2}{I_t^2} \right] =1 \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)

Demand for capital by firms must satisfy

$$\begin{aligned} E_t[(1+R_{t+1}) {RPS}_{t+1}] =\frac{E_t\left[ (1-\alpha ) \frac{P_{t+1}^W Y_{t+1}}{K_{t+1}}+(1-\delta ) Q_{t+1}\right] }{Q_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)

In (A.15) the right-hand side is the gross return to holding a unit of capital in from t to \(t+1\). The left-hand side is the gross return from holding bonds, the opportunity cost of capital and includes an exogenous risk premium shock \({RPS}_t\), which, for now, we leave unmodeled. We complete the setup with investment costs by defining the functional form

$$\begin{aligned} S(X)=\phi _X (X_t-(1+g))^2 \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)

where g is the balanced growth rate. The RBC model we have set out defines a equilibrium in output, \(Y_t\), consumption \(C_t\), investment \(I_t\), capital stock \(K_t\) and factor prices, \(W_t\) for labor and \(R_t\) for capital, and the price of capital \(Q_t\), given exogenous processes for technology \(A_t\), government spending \(G_t\) and the risk premium shock \({RPS}_t\).

The NK framework combines the DSGE characteristics of RBC models with frictions such as monopolistic competition—in which firms produce differentiated goods and are price setters, instead of Walrasian determination of prices—and nominal rigidities, in which firms face constraints on the frequency with which they are able to adjust their prices. Therefore, we now introduce a retail sector that uses a homogeneous wholesale good to produce a basket of differentiated goods for consumption

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}=\left( \int _{0}^{1}C_{t}(m)^{(\zeta -1)/\zeta }{d}k\right) ^{\zeta /(\zeta -1)} \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

where \(\zeta \) is the elasticity of substitution. This implies a set of demand equations for each intermediate good m with price \(P_{t}(m)\) of the form

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}(m)=\left( \frac{P_{t}(m)}{P_{t}}\right) ^{-\zeta }C_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)

where \(P_{t}=\left[ \int _0^1 P_{t}(m)^{1-\zeta } {d}m \right] ^{ \frac{1}{1-\zeta }}\). \(P_{t}\) is the aggregate price index.

Conversion of good m from a homogeneous output requires a cost \(c Y_t^W (m)\) where wholesale production uses the production technology (A.8). Thus

$$\begin{aligned} Y_t(m)= & {} (1-c) Y_t^W (m)\end{aligned}$$
(A.19)
$$\begin{aligned} Y_t^W= & {} (A_{t} h_{t})^{\alpha } K_{t}^{1-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(A.20)

To introduce price stickiness, we assume that there is a probability of \(1-\xi \) at each period that the price of each intermediate good m is set optimally to \(P_{t}^{0}(m)\). If the price is not reoptimized, then it is held fixed.Footnote 16 For each intermediate producer m the objective is at time t to choose \(\{P_{t}^0(m)\}\) to maximize discounted profits

$$\begin{aligned} E_{t}\sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \xi ^k D_{t,t+k}Y_{t+k}(m)\left[ P_{t}^{0}(m)-P_{t+k} {MC}_{t+k} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.21)

subject to (A.18), where \(D_{t,t+k}\) is now the nominal stochastic discount factor over the interval \([t,t+k]\). The solution to this is

$$\begin{aligned} E_{t}\sum _{k=0}^{\infty } \xi ^k D_{t,t+k}Y_{t+k}(m)\left[ P_{t}^{0}(m)-\frac{1}{ (1-1/\zeta ) }P_{t+k} {MC}_{t+k} {MS}_{t+k}\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.22)

In (A.22) we have introduced a markup shock \(MS_t\) to the steady-state markup \(\frac{1}{ (1-1/\zeta ) }\). By the law of large numbers, the evolution of the price index is given by

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t+1}^{1-\zeta }=\xi P_{t}^{1-\zeta }+(1-\xi )(P_{t+1}^{0})^{1-\zeta } \end{aligned}$$
(A.23)

In setting up the model for simulation and estimation, it is useful to represent the price dynamics as difference equations. Using the fact that for any summation \(S_t \equiv \sum _{k=0}^\infty \beta ^k X_{t+k}\), we can write

$$\begin{aligned} S_t= & {} X_t+\sum _{k=1}^\infty \beta ^k X_{t+k}=X_t+\sum _{k'=0}^\infty \beta ^{k'+1} X_{t+k'+1} \text{ putting } k'=k+1\nonumber \\= & {} X_t+\beta S_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.24)

and defining here the nominal discount factor by \(D_{t,t+k} \equiv \beta \frac{ \Lambda _{C,t+k}/P_{t+k}}{ \Lambda _{C,t}/P_t}\), inflation dynamics are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_t^0}{P_t}= & {} \frac{H_t}{J_t}\end{aligned}$$
(A.25)
$$\begin{aligned} H_{t}-\xi \beta E_t [\Pi _{t+1}^{\zeta -1} H_{t+1}]= & {} Y_{t} \Lambda _{C,t}\end{aligned}$$
(A.26)
$$\begin{aligned} J_{t}-\xi \beta E_t [\Pi _{t+1}^{\zeta }J_{t+1}]= & {} \left( \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}\right) Y_{t} \Lambda _{C,t} {MC}_{t}{MS}_t \end{aligned}$$
(A.27)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{t}:\quad 1= & {} \xi \Pi _{t} ^{\zeta -1}+(1-\xi )\left( \frac{J_{t}}{H_{t}}\right) ^{1-\zeta } \end{aligned}$$
(A.28)

Real marginal costs are no longer fixed and are given by

$$\begin{aligned} {MC}_t=\frac{P_t^W}{P_t} \end{aligned}$$
(A.29)

Nominal and real interest rates are related by the Fischer equation

$$\begin{aligned} E_t[1+R_{t+1}]=E_t \left[ \frac{1+R_{n,t}}{\Pi _{t+1}} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.30)

where the nominal interest rate is a policy variable, typically given in the literature by a standard Taylor-type rule:

$$\begin{aligned} \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t}}{1+R_n}\right) =\rho \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t-1}}{1+R_n}\right) +\theta _{\pi } \log \left( \frac{\Pi _{t}}{\Pi }\right) + \theta _{y} \log \left( \frac{Y_{t}}{Y}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.31)

In fact, we will model monetary policy in a more general way by formulating a Calvo-type forward/backward interest rate rule in inflation targets as in Levine et al. (2007) and Gabriel et al. (2009). This is defined by

$$\begin{aligned} \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t}}{1+R_n}\right)= & {} \rho \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t-1}}{1+R_n}\right) +\theta _{\pi } \log \frac{\Theta _{t}}{\Theta } +\phi _{\pi } \log \frac{\Phi _t}{\Phi }+\theta _{y} \log \left( \frac{Y_{t}}{Y}\right) +\epsilon _{{MPS},t}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(A.32)

where \(\epsilon _{{MPS},t}\) is a monetary policy shock and

$$\begin{aligned} \log \Phi _{t}= & {} \log \Pi _t +\tau \log \Phi _{t-1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.33)
$$\begin{aligned} \varphi E_t [\log \Theta _{t+1}]= & {} \log \Theta _t-(1-\varphi )\log (\Pi _t) \end{aligned}$$
(A.34)

The Calvo rule can be interpreted as a feedback from expected inflation (the \(\theta \log \frac{\Theta _{t}}{\Theta }\) term) and past inflation (the \(\phi \log \frac{\Phi _t}{\Phi }\) term) that continues at any one period with probabilities \( \varphi \) and \(\tau \), switching off with probabilities \(1-\varphi \) and \(1-\tau \). The probability of the rule lasting for h periods is \((1-\varphi )\varphi ^{h}\), hence the mean forecast horizon is \((1-\varphi )\sum _{h=1}^{\infty }h\varphi ^{h}=\varphi /(1-\varphi )\). With \(\varphi =0.5\), for example, we would have a Taylor rule with one-period lead in inflation (\(h=1)\). Similarly, \(\tau \) can be interpreted as the degree of backward-lookingness of the monetary authority.

This rule can also be seen as a special case of a Taylor-type rule that targets h-step-ahead (back) expected rates of inflation and past inflation rates (with \(h=1,2,\ldots ,\infty )\)

$$\begin{aligned} i_{t}=\rho i_{t-1}+\theta _{0}\pi _{t}+\theta _{1}E_{t}\pi _{t+1}+\theta _{2}E_{t}\pi _{t+2}+\cdots +\gamma _{1}\pi _{t-1}+\gamma _{2}\pi _{t-2}+\cdots , \end{aligned}$$
(A.35)

albeit one that imposes a specific structure on the \(\theta _{i}\)’s and \( \gamma _{i}\)’s (i.e., a weighted average of future and past variables with geometrically declining weights). This has an intuitive appeal and interpretation, reflecting monetary policy in an uncertain environment: the more distant the h-step-ahead forecast, the less reliable it becomes, hence the less weight it receives. In turn, past inflation has a typical Koyck-lag structure.

Note that we are approximating the behavior of the central bank with an instrument rule, rather than assuming that the monetary authority optimizes a specific loss function. Despite the lack of a substantial body of evidence for the Indian case, the forward/backward-looking Calvo-type formulation can be useful to analyze the RBI’s interest rate setting behavior. Bhattacharya et al. (2010), using VAR methods, find monetary policy in India to have weak transmission channels. On the other hand, however, Virmani (2004) reports on the potential forward/backward-looking behavior of the RBI using instrumental rules, suggesting that a backward-looking rule explains the data well. Our proposal nests both types of behavior and can therefore shed light on their relative importance.

The structural shock processes in log-linearized form are assumed to follow AR(1) processes

$$\begin{aligned} \log A_{t}-\log \bar{A}_{t}= & {} \rho _{A} (\log A_{t-1}-\log \bar{A}_{t-1})+\epsilon _{A,t}\\ \log G_t-\log \bar{G}_t= & {} \rho _G (\log G_{t-1}-\log \bar{G}_{t-1})+\epsilon _{G,t}\\ \log {MS}_t-\log MS= & {} \rho _{MS} (\log {MS}_{t-1}-\log {MS})+\epsilon _{{MS},t}\\ \log {RPS}_t-\log {RPS}= & {} \rho _{{RPS}} (\log {RPS}_{t-1}-\log {RPS})+\epsilon _{{RPS},t} \end{aligned}$$

where \({MS}={RPS}=1\) in the steady state (so \(\log {MS}=\log {RPS}=0\)), while the monetary policy shock \(\epsilon _{{MPS},t}\) is assumed to be i.i.d with zero mean. This completes the specification of the benchmark NK model.

B    Summary of Closed Economy Model

The following summarizes the dynamic model for the closed economy which applies to the foreign bloc. Note that the baseline model in Appendix A puts \(\lambda =0\) and shuts down the financial accelerator.

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{2,t}= & {} \Lambda (C_{2,t}, L_t)= \frac{(C_{2,t}^{(1-\varrho )}L_{2,t}^\varrho )^{1-\sigma }-1}{1-\sigma }\\ \Lambda _{C_2,t}= & {} (1-\varrho ) C_{2,t}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1} (1-h_{2,t})^{\varrho (1-\sigma )} ) \\ \Lambda _{L_2,t}= & {} \varrho C_{2,t}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )} L_{2,t}^{\varrho (1-\sigma )-1}\\ \Lambda _{C_2,t}= & {} \beta E_t\left[ (1+R_{t+1}) \Lambda _{C_2,t+1}\right] \\ \frac{\Lambda _{L_2,t}}{\Lambda _{C_2,t}}= & {} \frac{W_{t}}{P_t}\\ L_{2,t}\equiv & {} 1-h_{2,t}\\ h_{1,t}= & {} 1-\rho \\ C_{1,t}= & {} \frac{W_t h_{1,t}}{P_t}\\ h_{t}= & {} \lambda h_{1,t}+ (1-\lambda ) h_{2,t}\\ C_t^e= & {} \frac{1-\xi _e}{\xi _e}N_t\\ C_t= & {} \lambda C_{1,t}+(1-\lambda ) C_{2,t}+C_t^e\\ Y_{t}^W= & {} F(A_{t}, h_{t}, K_{t})=(A_{t} h_{t})^{\alpha } K_{t}^{1-\alpha }\\ Y_{t}= & {} (1-c)Y_{t}^W\\ \frac{P_{t}^W}{P_t} F_{h,t}= & {} \frac{P_{t}^W}{P_t}\frac{\alpha Y_t^W}{h_t} = \frac{W_{t}}{P_t}\\ P_{t}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}P_{t}^W \\ K_{t+1}= & {} (1-\delta ) K_t+(1-S(X_t))I_t\\ X_t\equiv & {} \frac{I_t}{I_{t-1}}\\ Q_t (1-S(X_t)-X_t S'(X_t))+ & {} E_t \left[ \frac{1}{(1+R_{t+1})}\, Q_{t+1} S'(Z_{t+1}) \frac{I_{t+1}^2}{I_t^2} \right] =1\\ E_t [(1+R_{t+1})\Theta _{t+1}]= & {} E_t [1+R_{k,t+1}] \\ 1+R_{k,t}= & {} \frac{ (1-\alpha _I) \frac{P_{t}^W}{P_{t}}\frac{Y_{t}^W}{K_{t}}+(1-\delta ) Q_{t}}{Q_{t-1}}\\ \Theta _t= & {} s \left( \frac{N_t}{Q_{t-1} K_t}\right) RP_t=k\, \left( \frac{N_t}{ Q_{t-1}K_t}\right) ^{-\chi }{RPS}_t \\ N_{t+1}= & {} \xi _e V_t +(1-\xi _e) D_t^{e}\\ D_t^e= & {} \bar{D}_t^e \text{(BGP } \text{ steady } \text{ state) } \\ V_t= & {} (1+ R_{k,t}) Q_{t-1} K_{t}-\Theta _{t}(1+R_{t})(Q_{t-1}K_{t}-N_t) \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} S(X_t)= & {} \phi _X (X_t-(1+g))^2\\ Y_{t}= & {} C_{t}+G_t+I_t\\ H_{t}-\xi \beta E_t [\Pi _{t+1}^{\zeta -1} H_{t+1}]= & {} Y_{t} \Lambda _{C,t}\\ J_{t}-\xi \beta E_t [\Pi _{t+1}^{\zeta }J_{t+1}]= & {} \left( \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}\right) Y_{t} \Lambda _{C,t}{MS}_t {MC}_{t} \\ 1= & {} \xi \Pi _{t} ^{\zeta -1}+(1-\xi )\left( \frac{J_{t}}{H_{t}}\right) ^{1-\zeta } \\ {MC}_t= & {} \frac{P_t^W}{P_t}\\ 1+R_{t}= & {} \frac{1+R_{n,t-1}}{\Pi _{t}} \\ \log A_{t}-\log \bar{A}_{t}= & {} \rho _{A} (\log A_{t-1}-\log \bar{A}_{t-1})+\epsilon _{A,t}\\ \log G_t-\log \bar{G}_t= & {} \rho _G (\log G_{t-1}-\log \bar{G}_{t-1})+\epsilon _{G,t}\\ \log {MS}_t-\log {MS}= & {} \rho _{MS} (\log {MS}_{t-1}-\log {MS})+\epsilon _{MS,t}\\ \log {RPS}_t-\log {RPS}= & {} \rho _{{RPS}} (\log {RPS}_{t-1}-\log {RPS})+\epsilon _{{RPS},t}\\ \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t}}{1+R_n}\right)= & {} \rho \log \left( \frac{1+R_{n,t-1}}{1+R_n}\right) +\theta \log \frac{\Theta _{t}}{\Theta } +\phi \log \frac{\Phi _t}{\Phi }+\epsilon _{{MPS},t}\\ \log \Phi _{t}= & {} \log \Pi _t +\tau \log \Phi _{t-1} \\ \varphi E_t [\log \Theta _{t+1}]= & {} \log \Theta _t-(1-\varphi )\log (\Pi _t) \end{aligned}$$

The steady state is given by the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{N}_t= & {} \frac{(1-\xi _e) \bar{D}_t}{(1-\xi _e (1+R_k))} \end{aligned}$$
(B.36)
$$\begin{aligned} 1+R_k= & {} (1+R)\,\, s\left( \frac{\bar{N}_t}{\bar{K}_t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(B.37)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\bar{K}_{t}}{\bar{Y}_{t}^W}= & {} \frac{1-\alpha }{R_k+\delta } \end{aligned}$$
(B.38)

Choose a functional form

$$\begin{aligned} s \left( \frac{\bar{N}_t}{Q \bar{K}_t}\right) =k \left( \frac{\bar{N}_t}{ Q\bar{K}_t}\right) ^{-\chi } \end{aligned}$$

We obtain \(\chi \) from econometric studies and we have data on the risk premium \(\Theta =\frac{1+R_k}{1+R}\) and leverage (= borrowing/net worth)

$$\begin{aligned} \ell = \frac{QK-N}{N}=\frac{QK}{N}-1=\frac{1}{n_k}-1 \end{aligned}$$

defining \(n_k \equiv \frac{N}{Q K}\). Then we can set the scaling parameter k from (B.37) as

$$\begin{aligned} k=\Theta n_k^\chi \end{aligned}$$

Then in the baseline steady state used to calibrate parameters, we put \(\bar{N}_t=n_k \bar{K}_t\) and calibrate \(\bar{D}^e\) from (B.36). The nonzero-inflation steady state and the calibrated k are given by

$$\begin{aligned} 1+R= & {} \frac{(1+g)^{1+(\sigma -1)(1-\varrho )}}{\beta }\\ 1+R_n= & {} \Pi (1+R)\\ Q= & {} 1\\ \bar{Y}_{t}= & {} (1-c) (h_t \bar{A}_{t})^{ \alpha } \bar{K}_{t}^{1-\alpha } \\ \frac{\varrho \bar{C}_{2,t}}{(1-\varrho )(1-h)}= & {} \bar{W}_{t} \\ \bar{C}_{1,t}= & {} \bar{W}_{t} h \\ \frac{\alpha P^W \bar{Y}_{t}^W}{P h}= & {} \bar{W}_{t}\\ \frac{\bar{K}_{t}}{\bar{Y}_{t}^W}= & {} \frac{1-\alpha }{R_k+\delta }\\ 1+R_k= & {} (1+R)\Theta \\ \Theta= & {} k\,n_k^{-\chi }=k\left( \frac{\bar{N}_t}{Q \bar{K}_t}\right) ^{-\chi }\\ \bar{I}_t= & {} (\delta +g) \bar{K}_{t}\\ \bar{Y}_{t}= & {} \bar{C}_{t}+ \bar{I}_t+\bar{G}_t \\ 1= & {} \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}\frac{P^W}{P} \\ \bar{N}_t= & {} n_k \bar{K}_{t} = \frac{(1-\xi _e) \bar{D}_t^e}{(1-\xi _e (1+R_k))} \text{(determines } \bar{D}_t^ e)\\ \end{aligned}$$

C    Summary of Standard Open Economy Model

For the small open economy as \(\nu \rightarrow 0\) and \(\text{ w }_C^*\rightarrow 1\), from (5) we have that \(\frac{1-\nu }{\nu } (1-\text{ w }_C^*) \rightarrow 1-\omega _C^*\). Similarly, \(\frac{1-\nu }{\nu } (1-\text{ w }_I^*) \rightarrow 1-\omega _I^*\).

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{C,t}:\quad \frac{1}{1+R_{n,t}}= & {} \beta E_t \left[ \frac{\Lambda _{C,t+1}}{\Lambda _{C,t}\Pi _{t+1}} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(C.39)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{W_t}{P_{C,t}}= & {} \frac{\Lambda _{L,t}}{\Lambda _{C,t}}= - \frac{\Lambda _{h,t}}{\Lambda _{C,t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.40)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{2,t}: \quad \Lambda _{C,t}= & {} (1-\varrho )C_{2,t}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1} (1-h_t)^{\varrho (1-\sigma )}\end{aligned}$$
(C.41)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{h,t}= & {} -C_{2,t}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )} \varrho (1-h_t)^{\varrho (1-\sigma )-1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.42)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{1,t}= & {} \frac{W_{t}h_{t}}{P_{C,t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.43)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}= & {} \lambda C_{1,t}+(1-\lambda )C_{2,t} \end{aligned}$$
(C.44)
$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{P_{F,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) :\quad 1= & {} \left[ \text{ w }_C \left( \frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{1-\mu _C }+(1-\text{ w }_C)\left( \frac{P_{F,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{1-\mu _C }\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C}\end{aligned}$$
(C.45)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}= & {} \frac{1}{[\text{ w }_C+(1-\text{ w }_C)\mathcal {T}_t^{1-\mu _C}]^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.46)
$$\begin{aligned} \text{ where } \mathcal {T}_t\equiv & {} \frac{P_{F,t}}{P_{H,t}}\nonumber \\ C_{F,t}= & {} \text{ w }_C \left( \frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{-\mu _C} C_{t}\end{aligned}$$
(C.47)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{F,t}= & {} (1-\text{ w }_C)\left( \frac{P_{F,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{-\mu _C} C_{t}\end{aligned}$$
(C.48)
$$\begin{aligned} {C_{H,t}}^*= & {} (1-\omega _C^*) \left( \frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t} {RER}_{C,t}}\right) ^{-\mu _C^*} {C_{t}}^*\end{aligned}$$
(C.49)
$$\begin{aligned} H_t: \quad H_t-\xi _H \beta E_t [\Pi _{H,t+1}^{\zeta -1} H_{t+1}]= & {} Y_t \Lambda _{C,t}\end{aligned}$$
(C.50)
$$\begin{aligned} J_t: \quad J_t-\xi _H \beta E_t [\Pi _{H,t+1}^{\zeta }J_{t+1}]= & {} \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}MS_t Y_t \Lambda _{C,t} {MC}_t \end{aligned}$$
(C.51)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{H,t}: \quad 1= & {} \xi _H \Pi _{H,t} ^{\zeta -1}+(1-\xi _H)\left( \frac{J_t}{H_t}\right) ^{1-\zeta } \end{aligned}$$
(C.52)
$$\begin{aligned} {MC}_t= & {} \frac{P_{H,t}^W}{P_{H,t}}=\frac{P_{H,t}^W/P_{C,t}}{P_{H,t}/P_{C,t}}=\frac{\frac{W_t}{P_{C,t}}h_t}{\alpha Y_t\frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.53)
$$\begin{aligned} h_t: \quad Y_{t}^W= & {} (A_{t} h_t)^\alpha K_{t}^{1-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(C.54)
$$\begin{aligned} Y_t= & {} (1-c) Y_t^W\end{aligned}$$
(C.55)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{H,t}^W}{P_{C,t}}:\quad \frac{P_{H,t}^W}{P_{C,t}}= & {} {MC}_t\frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.56)
$$\begin{aligned} Q_t: E_t \left[ 1+R_{t+1}\right]= & {} \quad \frac{E_t\left[ \frac{P_{H,t+1}^W}{P_{t+1}}(1-\alpha ) \frac{Y_{t+1}}{K_{t+1}}+(1-\delta ) Q_{t+1}\right] }{Q_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.57)
$$\begin{aligned} R_t: \quad 1+R_{t}= & {} \frac{1+R_{n,t-1}}{1+\Pi _{t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.58)
$$\begin{aligned} K_{t+1}= & {} (1-\delta ) K_t+(1-S(X_t))I_t\nonumber \\\,\,\,\, S',\, S''\ge & {} 0\,;\,\,S(1+g)=S'(1+g)=0\end{aligned}$$
(C.59)
$$\begin{aligned} X_t= & {} \frac{I_t}{I_{t-1}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.60)
$$\begin{aligned} S(X_t)= & {} \frac{\phi _I}{2}(X_t-(1+g))^2\end{aligned}$$
(C.61)
$$\begin{aligned} I_t:\quad \frac{P_{I,t}}{P_{C,t}}= & {} Q_t (1-S(X_t)-X_t S'(X_t))+E_t \left[ \frac{Q_{t+1} S'(X_{t+1})}{(1+R_{t+1})}\, \frac{I_{t+1}^2}{I_t^2} \right] \qquad \qquad \end{aligned}$$
(C.62)
$$\begin{aligned} I_{H,t}= & {} \text{ w }_I \left( \frac{P_{H,t}/P_{C,t}}{P_{I,t}/P_{C,t}}\right) ^{-\mu _I} I_t\end{aligned}$$
(C.63)
$$\begin{aligned} I_{F,t}= & {} (1-\text{ w }_I) \left( \frac{P_{F,t}/P_{C,t}}{P_{I,t}/P_{C,t}}\right) ^{-\mu _I} I_t \end{aligned}$$
(C.64)
$$\begin{aligned} I^*_{H,t}= & {} (1-\omega _I^*) \left( \frac{P_{H,t}/P_{C,t}}{P_{I,t}/P_{C,t} {RER}_{I,t}}\right) ^{-\rho ^*_I} I^*_t\end{aligned}$$
(C.65)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{I,t}}{P_{C,t}}= & {} \left[ \text{ w }_I \left( \frac{P_{H,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{1-\mu _I}+(1-\text{ w }_I) \left( \frac{P_{F,t}}{P_{C,t}}\right) ^{1-\mu _I}\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\mu _I}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.66)
$$\begin{aligned} Y_t: \quad Y_t= & {} C_{H,t}+I_{H,t}+C_{H,t}^*+I_{H,t}^*+ G_t\end{aligned}$$
(C.67)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{S_t}{S_{t-1}}= & {} \frac{{RER}_{C,t} \,\Pi _t}{\,\,\,{RER}_{C,t-1}\, \Pi _{t}^*}\end{aligned}$$
(C.68)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{F,t}: \quad \frac{\mathcal {T}_t}{\mathcal {T}_{t-1}}= & {} \frac{\Pi _{F,t}}{\Pi _{H,t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.69)
$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {T}_t: \quad {RER}_{C,t}= & {} \frac{1}{\left[ 1-\text{ w }_C+\text{ w }_C \mathcal {T}_t^{\mu _C-1}\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C} }\end{aligned}$$
(C.70)
$$\begin{aligned} {RER}_{I,t}= & {} \frac{1}{\left[ 1-\text{ w }_I+\text{ w }_I \mathcal {T}_t^{\mu _I-1}\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _I} }\end{aligned}$$
(C.71)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _t= & {} [\text{ w }_C (\Pi _{H,t})^{1-\mu _C}+(1-\text{ w }_C) (\Pi _{F,t})^{1-\mu _C}]^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C}\end{aligned}$$
(C.72)
$$\begin{aligned} \log (1+R_{n,t})/(1+R_n)= & {} \rho _r \log (1+R_{n,t-1})/(1+R_n)+(1-\rho _r)(\theta _\pi E_t[\log \Pi _{t+1}]/\Pi \nonumber \\&+\,\theta _s \log S_t/S)+\epsilon _{r,t+1}\end{aligned}$$
(C.73)
$$\begin{aligned} {RER}_t^r= & {} \frac{\Lambda _{C,t}^*}{\Lambda _{C,t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.74)
$$\begin{aligned} 1+R^*_t= & {} \frac{1+R^*_{n,t-1}}{1+\Pi ^*_{t}}\end{aligned}$$
(C.75)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{(1+R_{n,t}^*) \phi (\frac{S_t B_{F,t}^*}{P_{H,t} Y_t})} S_t B_{F,t}^*= & {} S_{t} B_{F,t-1}^*+TB_t\end{aligned}$$
(C.76)
$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\frac{S_t B_{F,t}^*}{P_{H,t} Y_t})= & {} \exp \left( \frac{\phi _B S_t B_{F,t}^*}{P_{H,t} Y_t}\right) \,;\,\, \phi _{B}<0\end{aligned}$$
(C.77)
$$\begin{aligned} TB_t= & {} P_{H,t}Y_t-P_{C,t} C_t -P_{I,t} I_t- P_{H,t} G_t \end{aligned}$$
(C.78)

Then the real exchange rate is given by

$$\begin{aligned} {RER}_{C,t}= & {} {RER}_t^d {RER}_t^r\\ {RER}_t^d: 0= & {} \quad E_t \left[ \frac{\Lambda _{C,t+1}}{\Lambda _{C,t}}\frac{{RER}_{t+1}^r}{{RER}_t^r} \frac{1}{\Pi _{t+1}^*} \left( \frac{1}{\phi (\frac{S_t B_{F,t}^*}{P_{H,t} Y_t})\exp (\epsilon _{UIP,t+1})}-\frac{{RER}_{t+1}^d}{{RER}_t^d}\right) \right] \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(C.79)

Shocks:

$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{A_{t+1}}{A}= & {} \rho _a \log \frac{A_{t}}{A}+\epsilon _{a,t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.80)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{G_{t+1}}{G}= & {} \rho _g \log \frac{G_{t}}{G}+\epsilon _{g,t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.81)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{{MS}_{t+1}}{{MS}}= & {} \rho _{{ms}} \log \frac{{MS}_{t}}{{MS}}+\epsilon _{{ms},t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.82)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{{UIP}_{t+1}}{{UIP}}= & {} \rho _{{UIP}} \log \frac{{UIP}_{t}}{{UIP}}+\epsilon _{{uip},t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.83)

If the ROW is not modeled explicitly we close the model with exogenous AR(1) shocks

$$\begin{aligned} \log (1+R_{n,t}^*)/(1+R_n^*)= & {} \rho _r^* \log (1+R_{n,t-1}^*)/(1+R_n^*)+\epsilon _{r,t+1}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.84)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{\Pi ^*_{t+1}}{\Pi ^*}= & {} \rho _\pi ^* \log \frac{\Pi _{t}^*}{\Pi ^*}+\epsilon _{\pi ,t+1}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.85)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{C_{t+1}^*}{C^*}= & {} \rho _c^* \log \frac{C_{t}^*}{C^*}+\epsilon _{c,t+1}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.86)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{I_{t+1}^*}{I^*}= & {} \rho _i^* \log \frac{I_{t}^*}{I^*}+\epsilon _{i,t+1}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.87)
$$\begin{aligned} \log \frac{\Lambda _{t+1}^*}{\Lambda ^*}= & {} \rho _\Lambda ^* \log \frac{\Lambda _{t}^*}{\Lambda ^*}+\epsilon _{\lambda ,t+1}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.88)

Otherwise \(R_{n,t}^*\), \(\Pi _t^*\), \(C_t^*\) and \(I_t^*\) are modeled as before. First, assume zero growth in the steady state: \(g=g^*=0\) and nonnegative inflation. Then we have

$$\begin{aligned} R_n : \quad 1+R_n= & {} (1+R_{n}^*)\phi \left( \frac{S B}{P}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(C.89)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{W}{P}= & {} -\frac{U_{L}}{U_{C}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.90)
$$\begin{aligned} U_{C}= & {} (1-\varrho )C_{2}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1} (1-L)^{\varrho (1-\sigma )} \end{aligned}$$
(C.91)
$$\begin{aligned} U_{L}= & {} -C_{2}^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )} \varrho (1-L)^{\varrho (1-\sigma )-1} \end{aligned}$$
(C.92)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{1}= & {} \frac{WL}{P_C} \end{aligned}$$
(C.93)
$$\begin{aligned} C= & {} \lambda C_{1}+(1-\lambda )C_{2} \end{aligned}$$
(C.94)
$$\begin{aligned} P_F/P_C : \quad 1= & {} \left[ \text{ w }_C \left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_C}\right) ^{1-\mu _C }+(1-\text{ w }_C)\left( \frac{P_{F}}{P_C}\right) ^{1-\mu _C }\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C} \end{aligned}$$
(C.95)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{H}}{P_C}= & {} \frac{1}{[\text{ w }_C+(1-\text{ w }_C)\mathcal {T}^{1-\mu _C}]^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.96)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{H}= & {} \text{ w }_C \left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_C}\right) ^{-\mu _C} C \end{aligned}$$
(C.97)
$$\begin{aligned} C_{F}= & {} (1-\text{ w }_C)\left( \frac{P_{F}}{P_C}\right) ^{-\mu _C} C \end{aligned}$$
(C.98)
$$\begin{aligned} {C_{H}}^*= & {} (1-\omega _C^*) \left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_C {RER}_C}\right) ^{-\mu _C^*} {C}^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.99)
$$\begin{aligned} H(1-\xi _H \beta )= & {} YU_{C} \end{aligned}$$
(C.100)
$$\begin{aligned} J (1-\xi _H \beta )= & {} \frac{1}{1-\frac{1}{\zeta }}Y U_{C} {MC} \end{aligned}$$
(C.101)
$$\begin{aligned} {MC} : \quad H= & {} J \end{aligned}$$
(C.102)
$$\begin{aligned} {MC}= & {} 1-\frac{1}{\zeta }=\frac{C_2}{\alpha Y\frac{P_H}{P_C}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.103)
$$\begin{aligned} Y= & {} (1-c)(A L)^\alpha K^{1-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(C.104)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{H}^W}{P_C}= & {} {MC}\frac{P_{H}}{P_C} \end{aligned}$$
(C.105)
$$\begin{aligned} K= & {} \frac{(1-\alpha ){MC}\frac{P_{H}}{P_C}Y}{(R+\delta )Q} \end{aligned}$$
(C.106)
$$\begin{aligned} 1+R= & {} \frac{1+R_n}{\Pi } \end{aligned}$$
(C.107)
$$\begin{aligned} I= & {} (g+\delta )K \end{aligned}$$
(C.108)
$$\begin{aligned} X= & {} 1 \end{aligned}$$
(C.109)
$$\begin{aligned} S(X)= & {} S'(X)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(C.110)
$$\begin{aligned} Q= & {} \frac{P_I}{P_C} \end{aligned}$$
(C.111)
$$\begin{aligned} I_{H}= & {} \text{ w }_I \left( \frac{P_{H}/P_C}{P_{I}/P_C}\right) ^{-\mu _I} I \end{aligned}$$
(C.112)
$$\begin{aligned} I_{F}= & {} (1-\text{ w }_I) \left( \frac{P_{F}/P_C}{P_{I}/P_C}\right) ^{-\mu _I} I \end{aligned}$$
(C.113)
$$\begin{aligned} I^*_{H}= & {} (1-\omega _I^*)\left( \frac{P_{H}}{P {RER}}\right) ^{-\mu ^*_I} I^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.114)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_I}{P_C}= & {} \left[ \text{ w }_I \left( \frac{P_H}{P_C}\right) ^{1-\mu _I }+(1-\text{ w }_I) \left( \frac{P_F}{P_C}\right) ^{1-\mu _I} \right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\mu _I}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.115)
$$\begin{aligned} Y= & {} C_{H}+I_{H}+ {EX}_C + {EX}_I+ G_t \end{aligned}$$
(C.116)
$$\begin{aligned} EX_{C}= & {} C_{H,t}^*=(1-\omega _{C,t}^*)\left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_{C} {RER}_{C}}\right) ^{-\mu _C^*} C^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.117)
$$\begin{aligned} EX_{I}= & {} I_{H,t}^*=(1-\omega _{I,t}^*)\left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_{I} {RER}_{I}}\right) ^{-\mu _I^*} I^* \end{aligned}$$
(C.118)
$$\begin{aligned} {RER}_C= & {} \frac{1}{\left[ 1-\text{ w }_+\text{ w }_C \mathcal {T}^{\mu _C-1}\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _C} } \end{aligned}$$
(C.119)
$$\begin{aligned} {RER}_I= & {} \frac{1}{\left[ 1-\text{ w }_I+\text{ w }_I \mathcal {T}^{\mu _I-1}\right] ^\frac{1}{1-\mu _I} }\end{aligned}$$
(C.120)
$$\begin{aligned} R^*_n : \quad 1= & {} \beta (1+R^*_{n})\end{aligned}$$
(C.121)
$$\begin{aligned} 1+R^*= & {} \frac{1+R_n^*}{\Pi ^*} \end{aligned}$$
(C.122)

The model is complete if we pin down the steady state of the foreign assets or equivalently the trade balance (TB). In other words, there is a unique model associated with any choice of the long-run assets of our SOE.Footnote 17 The trade balance is

$$\begin{aligned} TB=P_{H}Y- P_C C -P_{I} I- P_{H} G=\underbrace{P_H {EX}_C-(P_C C-P_H C_H)}_{\text{ Net } \text{ Exports } \text{ of } \text{ C-goods }} +\underbrace{P_H {EX}_I-(P_I I-P_H I_H)}_{\text{ Net } \text{ Exports } \text{ of } \text{ I-goods }} \end{aligned}$$
(C.123)

using (C.116), for some choice of TB, say zero.

The problem now is that we need to force the nonlinear model to this steady state even when the latter may not be completely accurate. A way of doing this is to add a term \(\theta _{tb} \log (TB_t/TB)\) to the Taylor rule with a very small \(\theta _{tb}>0\) so that when there is a trade surplus the rule makes the nominal exchange rate appreciate slightly.

Finally, we calibrate \(\omega _C\) and \(\omega _I\) using trade data. From (C.123) we have

$$\begin{aligned} cs_{imp}\equiv & {} \frac{\text{ C-imports }}{\text{ GDP }}=\frac{C_F}{Y}=c_y(1-\text{ w }_C)\left( \frac{P_{F}}{P_C}\right) ^{-\mu _C}\end{aligned}$$
(C.124)
$$\begin{aligned} is_{imp}\equiv & {} \frac{\text{ I-imports }}{\text{ GDP }}=\frac{I_F}{Y}=i_y(1-\text{ w }_I)\left( \frac{P_{F}}{P_I}\right) ^{-\mu _I}\end{aligned}$$
(C.125)
$$\begin{aligned} cs_{exp}\equiv & {} \frac{\text{ C-exports }}{\text{ GDP }}=(1-\omega _C^*)\left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_C {RER}_C}\right) ^{-\mu _C^*} c_y^* \frac{Y^*}{Y}=\frac{C_H^*}{Y}\end{aligned}$$
(C.126)
$$\begin{aligned} is_{exp}\equiv & {} \frac{\text{ I-exports }}{\text{ GDP }}=(1-\omega _I^*)\left( \frac{P_{H}}{P_I {RER}_I}\right) ^{-\mu _I^*} i_y^* \frac{Y^*}{Y}=\frac{I_H^*}{Y} \end{aligned}$$
(C.127)

Hence using data for shares \(cs_{imp}\), \(is_{imp}\), \(cs_{exp}\) and \(is_{exp}\), we can calibrate \(\omega _C\) and \(\omega _I\). Use data for India: \(cs_{imp}=0.10\), \(is_{imp}=0.15\), \(cs_{exp}=0.23\), and \(is_{exp}=0.02\) for \(TB=0\). With balanced steady-state growth, the balanced growth steady-state path of the model economy with or without investment costs is given by \(Q=1\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\bar{\Lambda }_{C,t+1}}{\bar{\Lambda }_{C,t}}\equiv 1+ g_{\Lambda _C}=\left[ \frac{\bar{C}_{t+1}}{\bar{C}_t} \right] ^{(1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1)} =(1+g)^{((1-\varrho )(1-\sigma )-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(C.128)

Thus from (C.39)

$$\begin{aligned} 1+R=\frac{(1+g)^{1+(\sigma -1)(1-\varrho )}}{\beta } \end{aligned}$$
(C.129)

Similarly for the foreign bloc

$$\begin{aligned} 1+R^*=\frac{(1+g^*)^{1+(\sigma ^*-1)(1-\varrho ^*)}}{\beta ^*} \end{aligned}$$
(C.130)

It is then possible to have different preferences, inflation and growth rates provided

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1+R_n}{1+R_n^*}= \phi \left( \frac{S B}{P}\right) = \frac{\Pi (1+R)}{\Pi ^*(1+R^*)} =\frac{\Pi \beta ^*}{\Pi ^* \beta }\frac{(1+g)^{1+(\sigma -1)(1-\varrho )}}{(1+g^*)^{1+(\sigma ^*-1)(1-\varrho ^*)}} \end{aligned}$$
(C.131)

which pins down the assets in the steady state.

D    Summary of Open Economy Model with Financial Frictions : Complete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Note that there are already two financial frictions in the previous model: Ricardian households pay a risk premium for their international borrowing there are liquidity-constrained households. To complete the model we add a financial accelerator consisting of

$$\begin{aligned} E_t [1+R_{k,t+1}]= & {} E_t\left[ \Theta _{t+1} \left( \varphi E_t \left[ (1+R_{t+1}) \right] + (1-\varphi ) E_t \left( (1+R_{t+1}^*) \frac{{RER}_{C,t+1}}{\,\,{RER}_{C,t}} \right) \right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(D.132)
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _t= & {} k\left( \frac{N_t}{Q_{t-1} K_t}\right) ^{-\chi }\end{aligned}$$
(D.133)
$$\begin{aligned} N_{t+1}= & {} \xi _e V_t +(1-\xi _e) D_t^{e}\end{aligned}$$
(D.134)
$$\begin{aligned} V_t= & {} (1+ R_{k,t}) Q_{t-1} K_{t}-\Theta _t \left[ \varphi (1+R_{t}) + (1-\varphi ) (1+R_{t}^*) \frac{{RER}_{C,t}}{\,\,{RER}_{C,t-1}}\right] (Q_{t-1}K_{t}-N_t)\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(D.135)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gabriel, V., Levine, P., Yang, B. (2016). An Estimated DSGE Open Economy Model of the Indian Economy with Financial Frictions. In: Ghate, C., Kletzer, K. (eds) Monetary Policy in India. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2840-0_15

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2840-0_15

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New Delhi

  • Print ISBN: 978-81-322-2838-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-81-322-2840-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics