Skip to main content

Impact of Liberalization on Indian Firms—Some Issues

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Indian Textile and Clothing Industry

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Economics ((BRIEFSECONOMICS))

  • 1068 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter incorporates the resultant implications of the withdrawal of MFA quota on the firm level activity and the industry level output and employment in addition to describing the significant changes brought about in the structure of the textile and clothing Industry of India. The first section, with the help of an analytical structure and its supporting empirical observations, shows the importance of expenditure on sales promotion and marketing activities in enhancing the penetration capacity of the domestic industry in the unleashed global market. The second section of the chapter shows that the industry, since the withdrawal of quota, has witnessed unprecedented concentration of firm level activities not only by size of operation but also by specific regions or states within the country, thereby creating some sort of inequality. Relating trade and labor market outcomes, the firm-level empirical estimates show that the export-oriented firms in India were not affected adversely and that the aggregate wage bill also rose during this period. The firm-level panel is supplemented by a state-level panel to capture the more aggregative impact of the withdrawal of MFA on the level of labor earnings in various regions of India. It is inferred that the aggregate state level wage bill falls as the profit level rises for the industry. The results also show that regional wage disparity has strong relation with regional disparity in firm-concentration at the level of the industry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This way of incorporating quota relaxation in the analysis may not be very refined, but it has the advantage of analytical simplicity and enables us to get some useful insights.

  2. 2.

    It is a phenomenon of international trade theory that an import quota generally raises the domestic price of imports and if the importing country is large, then creating excess supply of exports lowers the foreign price. Conversely, a withdrawal of quota reduces the domestic price of imports and raises the foreign price. In this model, the domestic firm is an exporter to a large importing country and therefore, the withdrawal of quota (measured by its tariff equivalence) will favor the firm by raising the price of its exports.

  3. 3.

    According to the definitions used by CMIE, ‘net exports’ of a firm indicates the difference between its foreign exchange spending and the foreign exchange earning. It refers to the net amount of the foreign exchange transactions.

  4. 4.

    ‘Sales promotion expenditure’ includes advertising and marketing expenses of the firms. By definition ‘advertising expenses’ are those expenses on advertising that pertain to the current accounting period. On the other hand ‘marketing expenses’ include discounts, rebates, and commission paid to the selling agents. Thus, almost all the expenses incurred on promotion of goods and services of a particular firm are included in the ‘sales promotion expenditure’.

  5. 5.

    According to CMIE database, ‘net sales’ is a data field that refers to the value of sales net of indirect taxes.

  6. 6.

    Some abbreviated forms are used in presenting the results, viz., NENS stands for ‘net exports over net sales’. Similarly, AENS and SPENS represent ‘advertising expenses over net sales’ and ‘sales promoting expenditure over net sales’ respectively. Descriptive statistics are presented in Table 3.7 in the Appendix.

  7. 7.

    The patterns of change are graphically demonstrated in Figs. 3.2 and 3.3 in the Appendix.

References

  • Abraham V, Sasikumar SK (2010) Labour cost and export behaviour of firms in Indian textile and clothing industry. Munich personal RePEc archive paper. Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/22784/MPRA. Paper No. 22784, posted 19. May 2010 15:39 UTC. March 16

  • Bair J, Peters ED (2006) Global commodity chains and endogenous growth: export dynamism and development in Mexico and Honduras. World Dev 34(2):203–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Egger H, Egger P, Kreickemeier U (2011) Trade, wages, and profits. University of Tübingen Working papers in economics and finance, No. 23

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbon P (2005) Governance, entry barriers, upgrading. Re-interpretation of some GVC concepts from the experience of African garment exports, Mimeo. Danish Institute for International Studies, Paper presented at the conference on ‘Global Production Networks,’ Yale University, May 2005

    Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi G (2004) Industrial adjustment in the North Carolina textile and clothing industry. In: Presentation at the global apparel/clothing Europe conference at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, 15–16 Oct 2004

    Google Scholar 

  • Gherzi Report (2003) Benchmarking of costs of production of textile products in India vis-à-vis China, Pakistan, Indonesia, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, Swiss Textile Organization

    Google Scholar 

  • Hashim DA (2005) Post—MFA: making the textile and garment industry competitive. Economic and Political Weekly, 8 Jan 2005

    Google Scholar 

  • Kathuria S, Martin WJ, Bharadwaj A (2003) Implications of abolition of multi fibre arrangement for India and South Asia. In: Mattoo A, Stern RM (eds) India and the WTO. World Bank and Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kar M, Kar S (2011) The multi fibre arrangement and South Asia. In: Murshed SM et al. (eds) South-South globalization: challenges and opportunities for development. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Knappe M (2003) Textiles and clothing: what happens after 2005? Int Trade Forum 2:16 (International trade center)

    Google Scholar 

  • Marjit S, Kabiraj T, Mukherjee A (2009) Quota as a competitive device. In: Kamagashi T, Zhao L (eds) International trade and economic dynamics: essays in memory of Koji Shimomura. Springer, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Marouani MA (2009) Is the end of the MFA a threat? Rev Dev Econ 13(1):99–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanbhag V, Nair AKG (2000) Winning ways for the future apparel business. Global Bus Press, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Tewari M (2006) Is price and cost competitiveness enough for apparel firms to gain market share in the world after quotas? A review. Global Econ J 5 6(4)

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations Commission on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) (2005) TNCs and the removal of textiles and clothing quotas. Current studies in FDI and development, UNCTAD, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • United States International Trade Commission (USITC) (2004) Textiles and apparel: assessment of the competitiveness of certain foreign suppliers to the US market. Washington, D.C. 2001; Report declassified in Jan 2004

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mausumi Kar .

Appendices

Documents

Government of India (2008), Annual Survey of Industries 2004–05, Central Statistical Organization, New Delhi.

Reserve Bank of India—Monthly Bulletin for the month of August, 2013 released by the Reserve Bank of India dated 12th August, 2013.

Appendix

Slope of curve I is expressed as \(\left( {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right)_{I} = \frac{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}{{R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime}}}\)

Similarly, slope of curve II is shown as \(\left( {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right)_{II} = \frac{{(\overline{P} - C^{\prime})q^{\prime\prime}_{2} - C^{\prime\prime}q_{2}^{\prime 2} }}{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}\)

Since the slopes are negative, we take the absolute values

$$\begin{aligned} \therefore \; \left| {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right|_{I} - \left| {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right|_{II} & = \left\{ { - \frac{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}{{R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime}}}} \right\} - \left\{ { - \frac{{(\overline{P} - C^{\prime } )q^{\prime\prime}_{2} - C^{\prime\prime}q_{2}^{\prime 2} }}{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}} \right\} \\ & = \frac{{(\overline{P} - C^{\prime})q^{\prime\prime}_{2} - C^{\prime\prime}q_{2}^{\prime 2} }}{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }} - \frac{{C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}{{R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime}}} \\ & = \frac{{(R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime})(\overline{P} - C^{\prime})q^{\prime\prime}_{2} - R^{\prime\prime}C^{\prime\prime}q_{2}^{\prime 2} + C^{\prime \prime 2} q_{2}^{\prime 2} - C^{\prime \prime 2} q_{2}^{\prime 2} }}{{(R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime})C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }} \\ & = \frac{\Delta }{{(R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime})C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }}\;({\text{as}}\;\Delta = (R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime})(\overline{P} - C^{\prime})q^{\prime\prime}_{2} - R^{\prime\prime}C^{\prime\prime}q_{2}^{\prime 2})\\ \end{aligned}$$

Now,

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{\Delta }{{(R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime})C^{\prime\prime}q^{\prime}_{2} }} < 0 \quad \left( {{\text{as}}\;\Delta > 0,(R^{\prime\prime} - C^{\prime\prime}) < 0,q^{\prime}_{2} > 0,C^{\prime\prime} > 0} \right) \\ & \therefore \; \left| {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right|_{I} - \left| {\frac{{{\text{d}}q_{1} }}{{{\text{d}}x}}} \right|_{II} < 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$

Hence, we can infer that the absolute slope of curve I is less than the absolute slope of curve II. As a consequence, it can be concluded that in Fig. 3.1 curve I is flatter than curve II. Tables 3.7, 3.8, 3.9, 3.10, 3.11, 3.12, 3.13, 3.14, 3.15, 3.16, 3.17, 3.18 and 3.19.

Table 3.7 Detailed descriptive statistics for the variables dealt with in Table 3.1
Table 3.8 Detailed descriptive statistics for the variables associated with Eq. 3.8
Table 3.9 Andhra Pradesh
Table 3.10 Gujarat
Table 3.11 Karnataka
Table 3.12 Madhya Pradesh
Table 3.13 Maharashtra
Table 3.14 Orissa
Table 3.15 Punjab
Table 3.16 Rajasthan
Table 3.17 Tamil Nadu
Table 3.18 Uttar Pradesh
Table 3.19 West Bengal

See Figs. 3.2 and 3.3.

Fig. 3.2
figure 2

Firm concentration over the years

Fig. 3.3
figure 3

Top percentile concentration over the years

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kar, M. (2015). Impact of Liberalization on Indian Firms—Some Issues. In: The Indian Textile and Clothing Industry. SpringerBriefs in Economics. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2370-2_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics