Skip to main content

Traditional and Modern Pollution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Environment in Economics and Development

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Economics ((BRIEFSECONOMICS))

  • 1001 Accesses

Abstract

Pollution is a key concern in environmental economics, and economists have used their models to argue that this market failure can be overcome by harnessing market signals. The simple model of pollution control makes the argument clear, but in practice, developing countries use diverse instruments to control industrial pollution. In developing countries traditional pollution is a major cause of disease. We want to reduce pollution because we think it has harmful effects, but how do we establish our knowledge of its effects? Establishing the causality convincingly is difficult, but was done by John Snow in the middle of the nineteenth century in the case of cholera. The simple model of pollution control suggests that we consider the benefit of pollution control, but how do we establish them? For many, environmental economics is synonymous with monetary valuation. Monetary valuation is achieved by using a theoretical model along with an econometric one. In a developing country context, if we dig deeper, we may recognize the role of norms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Agarwal B (1997) ‘Bargaining’ and gender relations, within and beyond the household. Feminist Econ 3(1):1–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2010) Identity economics: how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being. Princeton University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Bromley D, Anderson G (2012) Vulnerable people, vulnerable states: redefining the development challenge. Routledge, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Das S, Dayal V, Murugesan A, Uma R, Sehgal M, and Chhabra SK (2009) An integrated empirical model of health effects of air pollution: the case of mining in Goa, India. IEG discussion paper, Institute of Economic Growth, Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Ezzati M, Kammen DM (2002) The health impacts of exposure to indoor air pollution from solid fuels in developing countries: knowledge, gaps and data needs. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC [Discussion Paper 02–24]

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman AM (1993) The measurement of environmental and resource values: theory and methods. Resources for the Future, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedman DA (1991) Statistical models and shoe leather. Sociol Methodol 21:291–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freedman DA (2009) Statistical models: theory and practice. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1953) The methodology of positive economics. In: Friedman M (ed) Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington W, Portney PR (1987) Valuing the benefits of health and safety regulation. J Urban Econ 22:101–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattanayak SK, Pfaff A (2009) Behavior, environment, and health in developing countries: evaluation and valuation. Ann Rev Resour Econ 1:183–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitt MM, Rosenzweig MR, Hassan MN (2005) Sharing the burden of disease: gender, the household division of labor and the health effects of indoor air pollution. CID working paper No. 119, center for international development, Harvard University, Boston, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh I, Squire L and Strauss J (eds) (1986) Agricultural household models: extensions, applications and policy. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith KR (1993) Fuel combustion, air pollution exposure, and health: the situation in developing countries. Annu Rev Energy Env 18:529–566

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sterner T, Coria J (2012) Policy instruments for environmental and natural resource management. RFF Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Tufte ER (1997) Visual explanations. Graphics Press, Connecticut

    Google Scholar 

  • WHO (2009) Global health risks. Mortality and burden of disease attributable to selected major risks. World Health Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vikram Dayal .

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix I compare a few features of the basic theoretical model used to value reductions in morbidity due to air pollution (Freeman 1993) with the theoretical model used by Das et al. (2009) (discussed in Extension 3).

In Freeman sickness S = S (C, a, b) where C is concentration, a is averting activity, and b is mitigating activities. On the other hand, in Das et al., sickness of an individual depends on total exposure to pollution of that individual (which can vary between persons in a household) E, consumption of cooked food (CF), doctor-visits (D), individual characteristics (Zi), and household characteristics (Zhh): Si = Si(Ei, CFi, Di; Zi, Zhh). Total exposure incorporates time spent in different micro-environments, but unlike in some western cities where people may avoid going outdoors on bad days, here the concentration indoors, particularly in the kitchen, may be high. Here the only mitigating activity is doctor visits.

A marked contrast between Freeman and Das et al. is the more detailed treatment of total exposure, Ei, by Das et al.:

Ei = t io Co + t ik Ck + t iw Cw + t iin Cin where d denotes time, i indexes individuals, o is for outdoor, k for the kitchen, w for work, in for indoor and C denotes concentration. So Co, i.e. outdoor concentration is not assumed to be the dose as in Freeman, but is only one component of total exposure.

Another difference in the two models is the utility functions: in Freeman, this is U(X, f, S) where X, f and s are consumption, leisure and sickness respectively. In Das et al., U = U(SC, SAM, SAF, XNF) where S is sickness and X denotes consumption. The key difference is that in Das et al. children (C), adult males (AM) and adult females (AF) are distinguished.

Finally, in Freeman, time spent working is a choice variable, but in Das et al. there is a choice between time spent in several activities and associated micro-environments, including, in the case of adult females, cooking and gathering biomass for fuel.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dayal, V. (2014). Traditional and Modern Pollution. In: The Environment in Economics and Development. SpringerBriefs in Economics. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-1671-1_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics