Skip to main content

Transaction Cost, Technology Transfer, and Mode of Organization

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Trade, Globalization and Development
  • 1147 Accesses

Abstract

We develop a monopolistically competitive model for a closed economy without contract incompleteness. We show that if superior technology is not allowed to be transferred, integration would be the best mode of organization given that the transaction cost of intermediate input is not sufficiently small. However, transferability of technology calls for adding the dimension of factor intensity of input. We then prove that integration could be the better option only when input production technology is capital intensive. Thus, we validate the empirical claim of Antras (2003) from a perspective other than incomplete contract.

We are thankful to Avik Chakrabarti, Lei Yang for their constructive comments on an earlier draft of the paper. Comments from an anonymous referee are also acknowledged with thanks. Sugata Marjit acknowledges without implicating, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) endowment at the CSSSC for financial support. The usual disclaimer applies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Cost of corruption can also be considered as a part of transaction costs. Nevertheless, the essence of the arguments will remain same.

  2. 2.

    ϕ(β) essentially signifies the cost associated with technology transfer which, in turn, is a function of ratio of factors used. Hence, variable cost of production is influenced by such possibility as technology is transferred at certain cost.

  3. 3.

    A change in β indicates alteration in capital–labor requirement in producing the intermediate input only. In what follows, the cost of technology transfer also adjusts. We thank the referee for asking for a clarificatory note on this point.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Antras, P., & Helpman, E. (2007). Contracts and technology adoption. American Economic Review, 97(3), 916–943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P. (2003). Firms, contracts and trade structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1375–1418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P. (2005). Property rights and the international organization of production. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 25–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P. (2005b). Incomplete contracts and the product cycle. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1054–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P., & Helpman, E. (2004). Global sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 552–580.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brainard, S. L. (1997). An empirical assessment of the proximity-concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade (pp. 520–544). LXXXVII: American Economic Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. K., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1997). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity (pp. 297–308). LXXXVII: American Economic Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. (1993). Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Cambridge: Addison Wesley Longman, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration (pp. 691–719). XCIV: Journal of Political Economy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Integration vs. outsourcing in industry equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 85–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2004). Managerial incentives and the international organization of production. Journal of International Economics, 63, 237–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (2005). Outsourcing in a global economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1979). Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade. Journal of International Economics, 9(4), 469–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R. (1984). Multinationals, multi-plant economies, and the gains from trade (pp. 205–226). XVI: Journal of International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1993). Johnson Controls, Inc., Automotive Systems Group: The Georgetown, Kentucky Plant. Stanford Graduate School of Business Case S-BE-9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pack, H., & Saggi, K. (2001). Vertical technology transfer via international outsourcing. Journal of Development Economics, 65(2), 389–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal, K. (1983). Vertical specialization in a Ricardian model with a continuum of stages of production. Economica, 50(197), 71–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal, K., & Jones, R. W. (1982). The theory of trade in middle products. American Economic Review, 72(1), 16–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeile, W. J. (1997). U. S. intra-firm trade in goods. Survey of Current Business, LXXVII, 23–38.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Biswajit Mandal .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Integrating final good producer (G) maximizes the following profit function in absence of technology transfer.

$$ \pi_{G,\;I} (i) = p(i)x(i) - r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \gamma x(i) - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } $$
(A.1)

We further know that,

$$ x(i) = EP^{\sigma - 1} p(i)^{ - \sigma } $$
(A.2)

From (A.2) one gets,

$$ \frac{x(i)}{{\frac{\partial x(i)}{\partial p(i)}}} = - \frac{p}{\sigma } $$
(A.3)

The first-order condition implies

$$ \begin{gathered} p(i) - r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \gamma = \frac{p(i)}{\sigma } \hfill \\ p(i) = r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \frac{\gamma }{\alpha } \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.4)

Plugging (A.2) and (A.4) in (A.1), the profit equation reduces to

$$ \pi_{G,I} (i) = F\alpha^{\sigma } \gamma^{1 - \sigma } \left[ {\frac{1}{\sigma - 1}} \right]\left[ {r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } } \right]^{1 - \sigma } - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } $$
(A.5)

This is the same equation that we have in text as (13).

Following the same technique, we can derive the profit maximizing equilibrium price for G when input is sourced from stand-alone supplier.

$$ p(i) = r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \frac{\mu }{\alpha } $$
(A.6)

In what follows, the profit for G with outsourced intermediate input becomes,

$$ \begin{aligned} \pi_{G,I} (i) = & p(i)x(i) - r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \mu x(i) - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \\ \Rightarrow \pi_{G,O} (i) = & F\alpha^{\sigma } \mu^{1 - \sigma } \left[ {\frac{1}{\sigma - 1}} \right]\left[ {r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } } \right]^{1 - \sigma } - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A.7)

This equation is identical with (12′) of the main text.

However, with technology transfer (TT) the total cost function for producing intermediate input would be:

$$ C = (r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } )(1 + \phi (\beta ))x(i) + f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } $$
(A.8)

Therefore the profit equation becomes,

$$ \pi_{G,I} (i) = p(i)x(i) - r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } x(i)(1 + \phi (\beta )) - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } $$
(A.9)

Above equation gives us the new profit-maximizing equilibrium price as

$$ p(i) = r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } \frac{(1 + \phi (\beta ))}{\alpha } $$
(A.10)

Plugging (A.2), (A.8) ,and (A.10) into (A.9) one gets the equation identical with (16) of the main body of the paper.

$$ \pi_{G,I,TT} (i) = F\alpha^{\sigma } (1 + \phi (\beta ))^{1 - \sigma } \left[ {\frac{1}{\sigma - 1}} \right]\left[ {r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } } \right]^{1 - \sigma } - f_{c} r^{\beta } w^{1 - \beta } $$
(A.11)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mandal, B., Marjit, S. (2014). Transaction Cost, Technology Transfer, and Mode of Organization. In: Acharyya, R., Marjit, S. (eds) Trade, Globalization and Development. Springer, India. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-1151-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics