Skip to main content

Dualism in the Informal Economy: Exploring the Indian Informal Manufacturing Sector

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Development and Sustainability

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Bardhan (2009), in his critique of Sanyal and Bhattacharya (2009), has argued that exclusion may not be inherent in the process of capitalist development—he cites China as an example of a country that has possibly exhausted its reserve of surplus labor through a process of rapid capital accumulation. He argues that exclusion results from policies (not limited only to the oft-cited labor laws) that obstruct the pace and diffusion of capitalist accumulation. Within India, Bardhan argues, there are regional variations in the rate of capitalist accumulation and they can be attributed to the state-level policy differences. Noting the peculiarities of the Indian society, Bardhan concludes that “[t]he Indian transition is thus bound to be rather tortuous, though in the long run inexorable, and its narrative will be more complex than usual” (ibid: p.35). In the following section, on the basis of NSSO data on informal manufacturing sector in India, we argue that the informal sector, in terms of production relations, is largely constituted by a non-capitalist “outside” of capital. However, based on the limited empirical analysis in the space of this chapter, and the available data, we have no way to throw light on the processes (e.g. “exclusion” in Sanyal (2007) and Sanyal and Bhattacharya (2009)) behind persistence of such a non-capitalist “outside of capital”. Ultimately we differ with Bardhan on the ontology of capital that grounds our respective positions. Bardhan argues that a full transition to capitalism is inevitable, if only delayed due to policy interventions; we argue that policy interventions are endogenous to the process of capitalist development, being products of capital-labor contradictions within the circuits of capital. Hence, even if we accept that policy interventions are behind the persistence of informality, it only reinforces our argument that the nature of capitalist development itself renders its fullness impossible.

  2. 2.

    The survey included 2260 urban enterprises that were part of the “list frame” of the survey, comprising of “very big” non-ASI enterprises. These enterprises are included in the unorganized sector since they are not covered in the ASI, but their economic characteristics are very different from the other unorganized sector enterprises (e.g., the gross value of output for these enterprises in 2001 were more than six times the average value of output of the enterprises in the small-scale industry in the urban areas [NSSO 2007a, b: B-3]). These enterprises were not considered for the analytical purposes of this chapter. The remaining 80,637 enterprises (42,050 rural and 38,587 urban enterprises) from the “area frame” of the survey, covering 4,798 villages and 5,125 urban blocks from all the 29 states and 6 union territories, were considered for analysis. However, some of these enterprises do not conform to the definition of the informal sector (though they were part of the unorganized sector) and, hence, are not part of the present analysis. Of the 80,637 enterprises, it was found that 377 enterprises did not operate on a proprietary or partnership basis. Among the rest, 2,870 enterprises had 10 or more total worker, and an additional 25 enterprises did not have proper information on the total number of workers. These 3,272 enterprises were not considered for this analysis. Thus the present analysis is based on the remaining 77,365 sample enterprises, a subset of the unorganized manufacturing sector surveyed in the 62nd round (about 93 % of the original sample), representing an estimated 16,798,700 enterprises (about 98 % percent of the estimated population of unorganized enterprises) that conform to the international as well as the Indian definition of an informal enterprise. These informal sector enterprises engage an estimated 32,331,802 workers (i.e., about 88.7 % of the estimated 36,442,799 unorganized manufacturing sector workers; and about 71 % of all workers who are engaged in manufacturing activities, organized and unorganized). The population estimates from the sample for all analyses in this chapter are calculated by using the weights provided by the NSSO along with the unit-level data.

  3. 3.

    Resnick and Wolff (1987) characterize a class structure in terms of fundamental and subsumed class processes. The former refers to the production and appropriation of surplus labor produced by direct producers; the latter refers to the processes by which the appropriators of surplus labor distribute it to those who provide conditions of existence of the fundamental class process. The identification of a class structure as capitalist or non-capitalist (self-appropriative, feudal, slave, communist, etc.) depends on specifying the mode of appropriation of surplus, the particular political, cultural, economic, and natural conditions of existence of that mode and hence the subsumed classes responsible for providing those conditions. See Bhattacharya (2010) for the details and the implications of such classifications for the informal economy. In Sanyal (2007), the formal and informal economies are not class-specified, but are rather conceptualized around the logic of production—production for consumption/need in the “need-economy” and production for accumulation in the “accumulation-economy”. The “need-economy” and “accumulation-economy” can each accommodate both capitalist and non-capitalist enterprises. While both the above approaches are important in the context of understanding the informal economy, our purpose in this essay is limited. Given that the NSSO data does not allow us to precisely identify the mode of appropriation of surplus and its conditions of existence, nor does it allow us to identify the objective of production (need or accumulation), we treat enterprises with hired labor as capitalist enterprises and enterprises run on own and family labor as non-capitalist (self-appropriative) enterprises. DMEs and NDMEs have at least one hired laborer combined often with own and family labor, while OAMES are run soley on own and family labor. We understand DMEs and OAMEs as predominantly capitalist and non-capitalist (self-appropriative) in nature respectively, while NDMEs partake the character of both to substantial degrees. Of course, in identifying this way, we ignore other non-capitalist class processes involving family labor (e.g. feudal) in all of these enterprises. However, given the nature of the data such finer theoretical distinctions are hardly empirically tractable, though their theoretical significance needs to be acknowledged. In our analysis, predominance of a particular class process in an enterprise simply means the quantitative predominance of hired labor versus own plus family labor, as calculated from unit-level data.

  4. 4.

    Here we consider the positions of two part-time workers as one full-time position.

  5. 5.

    In Marxian terms, volume of surplus increases with the number of exploitable wage workers.

  6. 6.

    Think of health and education, both of which are normally accepted necessities for reproduction of labor power in the formal sector. Once socially established as a norm, it enters the subsistence basket of the informal producers too, although the ability to access such basic services in a privatized healthcare and education system is markedly different for the average formal and informal sector worker. In this case, the evolution of the capitalist economy—with its requirement of more productive, educated, and healthy labor force—influences the notion of subsistence in the noncapitalist economy. Just by looking at rising income and productivity in the noncapitalist informal economy, one cannot infer that accumulation is taking place, without making a prior assumption regarding the level of subsistence.

References

  • Arimah BC (2001) Nature and determinants of the linkages between informal and formal sector enterprises in Nigeria. Afr Dev Rev 13(1):114–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P (2009) Notes on the political economy of India’s tortuous transition. Econ Politi Wkly 44(49):31–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya R, Sanyal KK (2011) Bypassing the squalor: new towns, immaterial labour and exclusion in post-colonial urbanisation. Econ Politi Wkly XLVI(31):41–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya S (2010) Non/capital, class and development: The case of informal manufacturing in India. PhD Thesis, University of Notre Dame. Available at: http://etd.nd.edu/ETD-db/theses/available/etd-07232010-064338/unrestricted/BhattacharyaS072010.pdf. Accessed 4 March 2012

  • De Soto H (1989) The other path: the invisible revolution in the third world. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto H (2000) The mystery of capital: why capitalism succeeds in the west and fails everywhere else. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fajnzylber P, Maloney W, Rojas GM (2009) Microenterprise dynamics in developing countries: how similar are they to those in the industrialized world? evidence from Mexico. World Bank Econ Rev 20(3):389–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerry C (1987) Developing economies and the informal sector in historical perspective, Annals American Acad Pol Soc Sc, 493:100–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirway I (1999) Estimating work force using time use statistics in india and its implications for employment policies. Paper presented at the international seminar on time use studies, Ahmedabad, India, 7–10 Dec. Available at: http://hdrc.undp.org.in/resoruces/gnrl/ThmticResrce/gndr/Indira_Estimate.pdf. Accessed on 27 May 2005

  • House WJ (1984) Nairobi’s informal sector: dynamic entrepreneurs or surplus labor? Econ Dev Cult Chang 32(2):277–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Labour Office (1972) Employment, incomes and equality. A strategy for increasing productive employment in Kenya. ILO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labour Office (1985) Informal sector in Africa. Job and skills programme for Africa (JASPA). ILO, Addis Ababa

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Shleifer A (2008) The unofficial economy and economic development. Brookings Pap Econ Act 39(2):275–363

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney W (2004) Informality revisited. World Dev 32(7):1159–1178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandelman FS, Montes-Rojas GV (2009) Is self-employment and microentrepreneurship a desired outcome? World Dev 37(12):1914–1925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGee TG (1973) Peasants in the cities: a paradox, a paradox, a most ingenious paradox. Hum Organ 32(2):135–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Moser C (1978) Informal sector or petty commodity production? dualism or dependence in urban development? World Dev 6 :9–10

    Google Scholar 

  • NCEUS (National Commission for Enterprises in Unorganized Sector) (2008) Definitional and statistical issues: task force report. NCEUS, Government of India, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • NSSO (National Sample Survey Organization) (2007a) Operational characteristics of unorganized manufacturing enterprises in India, Round 62nd (2005-06) Report No. 524. Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation. Government of India, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • NSSO (National Sample Survey Organization) (2007b) Unorganized manufacturing sector in India: input, output and value-added. Round 62nd (2005–06) Report No. 526. Ministry of Statistics and Program Implementation. Government of India, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Nun J (2000) The end of work and the marginal mass thesis. Lat Am Perspect 27(1):6–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oshima HT (1971) Labour force explosion and the labour intensive sector in Asian growth. Econ Dev Cult Change 19(2):161–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Burger J, Field CB, Norgaard RB, Policansky D (1999) Sustainability: revisiting the commons: local lessons, global challenges. Science 284(5412):278–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portes A, Walton J (1981) Labor, class, and the international system. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Quijano A, Westwell P (1983) Imperialism and marginality in latin America. Lat Am Perspect 10(2/3):76–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranis G, Stewart F (1999) V-goods and the role of the urban informal sector in development. Econ Dev Cult Change 47(2):259–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Resnick SA, Wolff RD (1987) Knowledge and class. University of Chicago Press Ltd, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray D (1998) Development economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Sainz JPP (1998) The new faces of informality in central America. J Lat Am Stud 30(1):157–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahu PP (2010) Subcontracting in India’s unorganised manufacturing sector: a mode of adoption or exploitation? J S Asian Dev 5(1):53–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal KK (2007) Rethinking capitalist development: primitive accumulation, governmentality and post-colonial capitalism. Routledge, New Delhi and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanyal KK, Bhattacharya R (2009) Beyond the factory: globalisation, informalisation of production and the new locations of labour. Econ Politi Wkly 44(22):35–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Sethuraman SV (1975) Urbanization and employment: a case study of Djakarta. Int Labour Rev 112(2–3):191–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Tokman V (1978) An exploration into the nature of informal–formal sector relationships. World Dev 6(9/10):1065–1075

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rajesh Bhattacharya .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bhattacharya, R., Bhattacharya, S., Sanyal, K.K. (2013). Dualism in the Informal Economy: Exploring the Indian Informal Manufacturing Sector. In: Banerjee, S., Chakrabarti, A. (eds) Development and Sustainability. Springer, India. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-1124-2_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics