Skip to main content

Analyzing International Developmental Loan Markets with Rival Lenders

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Games of Conflict and Cooperation in Asia

Part of the book series: The Political Economy of the Asia Pacific ((PEAP))

  • 429 Accesses

Abstract

Despite the deepening of interdependence, international institutions are becoming increasingly fragmentary and unable to coordinate states’ policy choices. Such a coordination failure is serious in the realm of developmental finance, where major states vie against one another in extending loan contracts to developing states through separate institutions. Competitive lending is a double-edged sword: on the one hand, it may satisfy strong credit demands for infrastructure improvement in the developing world, while, on the other, it may also generate excessive lending and borrowing, increasing the risks of repayment difficulty and even sovereign debt default. Using a model of common agency, we analyze (1) how two lenders issue loan contracts with a single borrower to induce the foreign policy behaviors they prefer and (2) how the borrower determines its foreign policy to maximize loans. The analysis hypothesizes that, when the borrower assumes foreign policy neutralism, the lenders issue greater loan contracts than what they believe are optimal and that this excess persists as long as the lenders refuse to delegate the lending tasks to a common international financial institution that can sort out their varying preferences and provide common-agency control. We test this hypothesis against quantitative data pertaining to Cold War experiences and provide qualitative evidence on American and Soviet foreign economic policies. Our analytical results have implications for historical and contemporary Asian political economy.

Earlier versions of this chapter were presented at the International Workshop on Security and Economy in Tokyo on January 31, 2016, the International Political Economy Workshop in Kyoto on March 4, 2016, and the Annual Conference of the International Studies Association in Atlanta on March 19, 2016. The authors thank the conference and workshop participants and Professor Akira Okada for their comments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    One remotely related study is Drezner (2007), who analyzes a case of two major states coordinating their choices in setting up international standards. Unlike our analysis, this study omits international institutions as an intermediary for coordination and the response of a third-party.

  2. 2.

    In the similar policy domain of foreign economic aid, many analysts have examined how donor states utilize aid money to promote their geopolitical and commercial interests and have also evaluated donors’ creative strategies such as earmarking and trust funds (Alesina and Dollar 2000; Burnside and Dollar 2000; Dietrich 2013; Eichenauer and Reinsberg 2016; Knack 2014). However, they have not investigated the process and consequence of aid competition between donors with divergent interests. Our analysis helps fill this analytical lacuna.

  3. 3.

    More precisely, our complete-information model of common agency generates inefficiency solely from an inter-principal coordination failure, not from incomplete information.

  4. 4.

    The data are obtained from the following sources:

    1. 1.

      US grant aid and loans from the United States Agency for International Development (https://www.usaid.gov/results-and-data, last accessed on March 1, 2016).

    2. 2.

      GDP and population from the World Development Indicators provided by the World Bank (http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators, last accessed on March 1, 2016).

    3. 3.

      Ideal points from the United Nations General Assembly Voting Data by Eric Voeten (https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=hdl:1902.1/12379, last accessed on March 1, 2016).

  5. 5.

    The statistical analysis of Carbonnier and Voicu (2014), using a larger dataset with 15 OECD donors and 162 recipients covering 1972–2011, found that, in general, aid by rich Western states, including the United States, is correlated positively and significantly with the NAM.

  6. 6.

    As an example, we cite data on Soviet grant aid and loans to Indonesia (Boden 2008, pp. 116–7). From 1959 to 1965, Indonesia received an extraordinarily large share of Soviet aid. The Soviet Union supplied Indonesia with 789 million rubles’ worth of assistance during those years, more than one-fifth (21 %) of the total amount provided by Moscow to all non-socialist developing states. The assistance provided to Indonesia was mostly in the form of loans, which outweighed grants by roughly 14 to 1. Soviet experts insisted that effective aid had to take the form of loans rather than grants.

  7. 7.

    Correspondingly, from 1950 to 1965, the United States provided Indonesia with some $650 million in aid, consisting of $387 million in loans and $264 million in non-reimbursable grant money. Of the $650 million total, about $68 million was in military aid. US aid declined precipitously after 1963, when the regional communist movement Konfrontasi escalated; in 1964, the total was $40 million; in 1965, the number was actually negative (presumably because Indonesia made repayments; Webster 2009).

  8. 8.

    Bader (2016) also compares the contemporary Chinese financial initiative to the medieval tributary system.

  9. 9.

    “ADB Says will Maintain Standards When Cooperating with AIIB,” Reuters, May 2, 2015 (http://www.reuters.com/article/us-asia-adb-aiib-idUSKBN0NN07920150502, last accessed on July 26, 2016).

  10. 10.

    Michael Martina and Wroughton, “Diplomatic Win for China as ASEAN Drops Reference to Maritime Court Ruling,” Reuters, July 25, 2016 (http://www.reuters.com/article/us-southchinasea-ruling-asean-idUSKCN1050F6, last accessed on July 26, 2016).

References

  • Alesina, A., & Dollar, D. (2000). Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 33–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asian Development Bank (ADB). (2009, August 31). Infrastructure for a seamless Asia. ADB report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bader, J. (2016). How Xi jinping see the world…and why? Asia working group paper (Vol. 2). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, D., & Whinston, M. (1986). Common agency. Econometrica, 54(4), 923–942.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bizer, D., & DeMarzo, P. (1992). Sequential banking. Journal of Political Economy, 100(1), 41–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boden, R. (2008). Cold war economics: Soviet aid to Indonesia. Journal of Cold War Studies, 10(3), 110–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buszynski, L. (1986). Soviet foreign policy and Southeast Asia. London: Croom Helm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carbonnier, G., & Voicu, S. (2014). The drivers of foreign aid allocation during the cold war, energy crises and the global war on terror. Geneva: Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dietrich, S. (2013). Bypass or engage? explaining donor delivery tactics in foreign aid allocation. International Studies Quarterly, 57(4), 698–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1997). Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policy making. Journal of Political Economy, 105(4), 753–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drezner, D. W. (2007). All politics is global: Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichenauer, V. Z., & Reinsberg, B. (2016). What determines earmarked funding to international development organizations?: Evidence from the new multi-bi aid data. CIS working paper 88. Center for Comparative and International Studies (CIS), University of Zurich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finnemore, M. (2003). The purpose of intervention. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giplin, R. (1983). War and change in world politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grimes, W. (2008). Currency and contest in East Asia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D., et al. (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J., & Shipan, C. (2008). Politics, delegation, and bureaucracy. In B. R. Weingast & D. Wittman (Eds.), The oxford handbook of political economy (pp. 256–272). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein, P. (2005). A world of regions: Asia and Europe in the American imperium. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1981). Dominance and leadership in the international economy. International Studies Quarterly, 25(2), 242–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (2014). Building or bypassing recipient country systems: Are donors defying the Paris declaration? Journal of Development Studies, 50(6), 839–854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. (1976). State power and the structure of international trade. World Politics, 28(3), 317–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. (1991). Global communications and national power: Life on the Pareto frontier. World Politics, 43(3), 336–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J., & Martimont, D. (2002). The theory of incentives: The principal-agent model. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H. V., & Mansfield, E. D. (Eds.). (1997). The political economy of regionalism. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, T. (2016, April 19). China’s AIIB seeks to pave new silk road with first projects. Financial Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1997). Taking preferences seriously: A liberal theory of international politics. International Organization, 51(4), 513–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peselj, B. (1964). Communist economic offensive: Soviet foreign aid—means and effects. Law and Contemporary Problems, 29(1), 983–999.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C. M. (2010). This time is different chartbook: Country histories on debt, default, and financial crises. Working paper 15815, National Bureau of Economic Research http://www.nber.org/papers/w15815. Last accessed on 1 March 2016.

  • Reinhart, C., & Rogoff, K. (2009). This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singam, A. W., & Hune, S. (1986). Non-alignment in an age of alignments. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stojanovic, R. (1981). The emergence of the non-aligned movement: A view from Belgrade. Case Western Reserve Journal of International Law, 13(3), 443–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strydom, H. (2008). Non-aligned movement and the reform of international relations. Max Planck Yearbook of United Nations Law Online, 11, 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webster, D. (2009). Regimes in motion: The Kennedy administration and Indonesia’s new frontier, 1960–1962. Diplomatic History, 33(1), 95–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Motoshi Suzuki .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Japan KK

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Suzuki, M., Iida, K., Doi, S. (2017). Analyzing International Developmental Loan Markets with Rival Lenders. In: Suzuki, M., Okada, A. (eds) Games of Conflict and Cooperation in Asia. The Political Economy of the Asia Pacific. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-56466-9_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics