Advertisement

Introduction

  • Michiko Iizuka
  • Akio Hosono
  • Jorge Katz
Chapter

Abstract

The Chilean salmon industry accounts for around one third of salmon production in the world, and is, along with Norway, one of the two largest producers of salmon (SalmonChile 2008). For a country which is still very much dependent upon copper exports, exports of salmon currently provide a significant proportion of Chilean export revenue (5 %). The fish is an exotic species to Chile, and the miraculous speed in which the country became a top exporter was thus achieved through intensive learning efforts in collaboration with various stakeholders, beginning as early as the 1960s.

Keywords

Salmon Farming Capture Fishery Infectious Salmon Anaemia Salmon Industry Copper Export 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Bibliography

  1. Acemoglu, D., and J. Robinson. 2012. Why nations fail. London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. 2005. Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In Handbook of economic growth, vol. 1A, ed. P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, 385–472. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  3. ADB. 2012. In chapter 8Google Scholar
  4. Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. A model of growth through creative destruction. Ecoometrica 60(2): 323–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Agosin, M.R. 1999. Trade and growth in Chile. Cepal Review 68: 72–100.Google Scholar
  6. Amsden, A. 1989. Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Aoki, M. 2007. Endogenizing institutions and institutional changes. Journal of Institutional Economics 3: 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Argote, M. 2003. Chile Performance: La mas complete guia para hacer negocios en Chile. Santiago: Editorial Puyehue.Google Scholar
  9. Auty, R. 1990. Resource-based industrialization: Sowing the oil in eight developing countries. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Auty, R. 2001. Resource abundance and economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Barton, J., and W. Murrray. 2009. Grounding geographies of economic globalization: Globalized spaces in Chile’s non-traditional export sector, 1980–2005. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 100(1): 81–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Bell, M., and K. Pavitt. 1995. The development of technological capabilities. In Trade, technology and international competitiveness, ed. I.U. Haque, 69–102. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  13. Chang, H.J. 2003. Kicking away the ladder – Infant industry promotion in historical perspective. Oxford Development Studies 31(1): 21–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Chang, H-J. 2011. Industrial policy: can we go beyond an unproductive confrontation? In Annual World Bank conference on development economics 2010: Global lessons from East Asia and the global financial crisis, eds. Justin Yifu Lin, Boris Pleskovic. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  15. Cimoli, M., and J. Katz. 2003. Structural reforms, technological gaps and economic development: A Latin American perspective. Industrial and Corporate Change 12(2): 387–411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Cimoli, M., G. Dosi, R.R. Nelson, and J. Stiglitz. 2006. Institutions and policies shaping industrial development: An introductory note. LEM Papers Series 2006/02, Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM). Pisa: Sant’Anna School of Advanced Studies. http://ideas.repec.org/p/ssa/lemwps/2006-02.html. Accessed 23 Oct 2008.
  17. Cimoli, M., G. Dosi, and J. Stiglitz. 2009. Industrial policy and development: Political economy of capabilities, accumulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Costanza, R., R. d’Arge, R. de Groot, S. Farberk, M. Grasso, B. Hannon, K. Limburg, S. Naeem, R. O’Neill, J. Paruelo, R. Raskin, P. Suttonkk, and M. van den Belt. 1992. The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature 387: 253–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Cozzens, S. and J. Sutz. 2012. Innovation in informal settings: A research agenda. Mimeo, 28 July. http://www.crdi.ca/EN/Lists/Publications/Attachments/1130/IID%20Framework%20July%2029.pdf. Accessed Sept 2013.
  20. Daly, H., and J.B. Cobb. 1994. For the common good: Redirecting the economy toward community, the environment, and a sustainable future. Boston: Beacon.Google Scholar
  21. David, P. 1993. Intellectual property institutions and the panda’s thumb: Patents, copy rights and trade secrets in economic theory and history. In Global dimensions of intellectual property rights in science and technology, ed. M.B. Wallerstein, Me. Mogee, and R.A. Schoen, 19–64. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  22. De Ferrati, D.M. 2002. From natural resource to the knowledge economy: Trade and job quality. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. ECLAC. 2000. Panorama de la Insercion International de America Latin y el Caribe. Santiago: Economic Commission for Latin America and Caribbean, United Nations.Google Scholar
  24. ECLAC. 2002. Globalization and development, Santiago, Chile Economic Commission for Latin America and Caribbean. United Nations.Google Scholar
  25. FAO. 2008. The state of world fisheries and aquaculture. Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
  26. FAO. 2014. Fishery and aquaculture statistics 2012. Rome: FAO.Google Scholar
  27. Fu, X., C. Pietrobelli, and L. Soete. 2011. The role of foreign technology and indigenous innovation in the emerging economies: Technological change and catch up. World Development 39(7): 1204–1212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Greif, A. 2006. Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Hardin, G. 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162: 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Hausmann, R., and D. Rodrik. 2005. Self-discovery in a development strategy for El Salvador. Economia 6(1): 43–101.Google Scholar
  31. Hawken, P., A. Lovins, and H. Lovins. 1999. Natural capitalism: Creating the next industrial revolution. Boston: Little Brown Publications.Google Scholar
  32. Hosono, A. 2010. Nambei Chili wo sake yushutsu taikoku ni kaeta Nihonjintachi (The Japanese who transformed Chile into a major salmon exporter). Tokyo: Daiyamondo-sha.Google Scholar
  33. Howells, J. 2006. Intermediation and the role of intermediaries in innovation. Research Policy 35: 715–728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Iizuka, M. 2007. Global standards and local producers knowledge governance and the rise of the Chilean salmon industry. PhD dissertation, University of Sussex.Google Scholar
  35. Katz, J. 2001. Structural reforms and technological behavior: The sources and nature of technological change in Latin America in the 1990s. Research Policy 30: 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Katz, J. 2006. Economic, institutional and technological forces inducing the successful inception of salmon farming in Chile. In Technology, adaption and exports: How some countries got it right, ed. V. Chandra, 193–224. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  37. Koh, L.P., and D.S. Wilcove. 2007. Cashing in palm oil for conservation. Nature 448: 993–994. The World Economy 8(2): 93–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Lenzen, M., D. Moran, K. Kanemoto, B. Foran, L. Lobefaro, and A. Geschke. 2012. International trade drives biodiversity threats in developing nations. Nature 486: 109–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Lin, J. 2011. New structural economics: A framework for rethinking development. The World Bank Research Observer 26: 193–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Lin, J.Y., and H. Chang. 2009. DPR debate: Should industrial policy in developing countries conform to comparative advantage or defy it? Development Policy Review 27(5): 483–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Lundvall, B.Å. 2010. National systems of innovation–towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning. New York: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
  42. Marine Harvest. 2012. Salmon farming industry handbook 2012. Oslo: Marine Harvest ASA.Google Scholar
  43. Marine Harvest. 2014. Salmon farming industry handbook 2014. Oslo: Marine Harvest ASA.Google Scholar
  44. Martinez-Alier, J. 1990. Ecological economics: Energy, environment and society. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  45. Mazzoleni, R., and R.R. Nelson. 1998. The benefit s and cots of strong patent protection: A contribution to the current debate. Research Policy 27: 273–284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Meller, P., and R.E. Saez. 1997. Auge Exportador Chileno: lecciones y desafios futuros. Santiago: Cieplan y Dolmen.Google Scholar
  47. Montero, C. 2004. Formación y Desarrollo de un Clúster Globalizado: El Caso de la Industria del Salmón en Chile. Santiago: ECLAC, United Nations.Google Scholar
  48. Naunde, W. 2010. New challenges for industrial policy. Working paper No 2010/107, UNWIDER, September, 2010.Google Scholar
  49. Nelson, R. 2008. What enables rapid economic progress: What are the needed institutions? Research Policy 37: 1–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Nelson, R., and B. Sampat. 2001. Making sense of institutions as a factor shaping economic performance. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 44: 31–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Nihon Keizai Shinbun. 2014a. Consumption of fish filled by farming. Nihon Keizai Shinbun. 3rd November 2014Google Scholar
  52. Nihon Keizai Shinbun. 2014b. Salmon cultue nurtured by Castle Town, Niigata Murakami. Nihon Keizai Shinbun. 18th November 2014Google Scholar
  53. Nissanke, M., and E. Thorbecke. 2010. Globalization, poverty and inequality in Latin America: Finding from case studies. World Development 38(6): 797–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Noman, A., K. Botchwey, H. Stein, and J.E. Stigliz. 2012. Good growth and the governance in Africa: Rethinking development strategies, the initiative for policy Dialogue. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  55. Nordhaus, W.D. 1969. Invention, growth and welfare, a theoretical treatment of technological change. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  56. North, D. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. North, D. 1991. Institutions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 97–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Odagiri, H., A. Goto, A. Sunami, and R.R. Nelson. 2010. Intellectual property rights, development, and catch up. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. OECD. 2007. Chile OECD reviews of innovation policy. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
  60. OECD. 2012. Innovation and inclusive development: Discussion report. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
  61. OECD. 2013. Perspectives on global development 2013: Industrial policies in a changing world shifting up a gear. Paris: OECD Development Center.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: Evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Ostrom, E., J. Burger, C.B. Field, R.B. Norgaard, and D. Policansky. 1999. Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science 284: 278–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Pardey, P.G., J.M. Alston, and V.W. Ruttan. 2010. The economics of innovation and technical change in agriculture. In Handbook of economics of technical change, ed. B.H. Hall and N. Rosenberg, 939–984. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  65. Pietrobelli, C., and R. Rabellotti. 2011. Global value chains meet innovation systems: Are there learning opportunities for developing countries? World Development 39(7): 1261–1269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Rodrik, D. 2001. Development strategies for the 21st century. Paper presented at the Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 2000, Washington, DC, April 8.Google Scholar
  67. Rodrik, D. 2007. One economics, many recipes: Globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  68. Rodrik, D., and R. Hausmann. 2003. Economic development as self-discovery. Journal of Development Economics 72: 603–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Romer, R.M. 1987. Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. American Economic Review 77(2): 56–62.Google Scholar
  70. Romer, R.M. 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98(5,2): S71–S102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Sato, J. 2011. State inaction in resource governance: Natural resource control and bureaucratic oversight in Thailand. JICA-RI Working Paper No 36. Tokyo: JICA Research Institute.Google Scholar
  72. Scott, W.R. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Ideas, Interests and Identities. Los Angeles, Sage.Google Scholar
  73. Stiglitz, J.E. 1999. Knowledge as a global public good. In Global public goods: International cooperation in the 21st century, ed. I. Kaul, I. Grunberg, and M. Stern. New York: Office of Development Studies (ODS), Bureau for Development Policy (BDP), United Nations Development Programme (UNDP).Google Scholar
  74. UN/DESA. 2012. Statistical annex, country classification. New York: UN/DESA. http://www.un.org/en/development/desa/policy/wesp/wesp_current/2012country_class.pdf#page=10&zoom=auto,-12,726. Accessed 3 June 2015
  75. UNEP. 2011. Towards a green economy: Pathways to sustainable development and poverty eradication—A synthesis for policy makers. Accessed 28th Jun 2012. www.unep.org/greeneconomy.
  76. Van Wijk, J., and G. Junne. 1993. Intellectual property protection of advanced technology. Changes in the global technology system: Implications and options for developing countries. Maastricht: UNU/INTECH.Google Scholar
  77. Verspagen, B. 2003. Intellectual property rights in the world economy. In Economics, law and intellectual property, ed. O. Granstrand, 489–518. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Wade, R. 1990. Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asia’s industrialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  79. Wade, R. 2010. After the crisis: Industrial policy and the developmental state in low-income countries. Global Policy 1(2): 150–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Wade, R. 2012. Return of industrial policy. International Review of Applied Economics 26(2): 223–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Warwick, K. 2013. Beyond industrial policy: Emerging issues and new trends. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers, No. 2, Paris: OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
  82. Williamson, John. 1999. What should the bank think about Washington Consensus? Paper prepared as a background to the World Bank’s World Development Report, 2000, Jul 1999.Google Scholar
  83. Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  84. Williamson, O. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  85. Williamson, O. 1998. The institutions of governance. The American Economic Review 88(2): 75–79.Google Scholar
  86. World Bank. 1993. The East Asian miracle: Economic growth and public policy. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  87. World Bank. 2013a. Fish to 2030. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
  88. World Bank. 2013b. World development report 2013. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© JICA Research Institute 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Maastricht Economic and Social Research and Training Center for Innovation and Technology (UNU-MERIT)United Nations UniversityMaastrichtThe Netherlands
  2. 2.Japan International Cooperation Agency Research Institute (JICA-RI)TokyoJapan
  3. 3.University of ChileSantiagoChile

Personalised recommendations