Skip to main content

Optimal Partial Privatization in an International Mixed Oligopoly Under Various Tax Principles

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Theory of Mixed Oligopoly

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 14))

Abstract

This chapter considers optimal privatization policy in an international mixed oligopoly. Allowing for partial privatization and cost asymmetry, we analyze the optimal policies under various tax regimes: arbitrary taxation, origin principle, destination principle, import tariffs, and a combination of tax and import tariffs. Our main results are as follows. First, when the government can arbitrarily levy taxes on a public firm’s output, maximum welfare is independent of the degree of privatization as long as the public firm is at least partially privatized. Second, under tax schemes that restrict freedom of taxation, an optimal privatization policy depends on tax regimes and cost asymmetry. Third, the elimination of import tariffs and the privatization of public firms improve both domestic welfare and a foreign competitor’s profit if a production subsidy is introduced in exchange for tariff elimination. Our results suggest that fiscal incentives such as tax and subsidies are superior in maximizing welfare when compared with managerial incentives such as public ownership.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Kowalski et al. (2013) calculated the weighted share of public firms for sales, profits, assets, and market values among a country’s top ten companies in 38 developed or developing countries. They pointed out that although the public enterprise sector in the OECD area has become significantly smaller, among emerging countries including Brazil, Russia, India, Indonesia, and China, state presence in the economy remains significant.

  2. 2.

    According to Solano and Sennekamp (2006), provisions for state enterprises and state monopolies that contain specific regulations for such firms were found in 55 of the 86 regional trade agreements they investigated.

  3. 3.

    Mujumdar and Pal (1998) considered the effect of indirect taxation on welfare and government revenue in a mixed oligopoly. They argued that the results substantially differ from that of a pure oligopoly.

  4. 4.

    In what follows, we do not exclude the possibility that the profit of the public firm becomes negative at the equilibrium. Indeed, in the model consisting of linear demand and quadratic cost functions discussed in Sect. 3, a public firm that emphasizes welfare may fall into deficit.

  5. 5.

    See Appendix A.6.1. Together with the convexity of the cost function and diminishing marginal revenue of the private firms, \( \left|{\phi}_f^d{\phi}_d^f\right|<1 \) is met. However, we cannot exclude the possibility of \( \left|{\Delta}_2\right|>1 \) without any restriction of ϕ 0 i .

  6. 6.

    If \( \theta =0 \), optimal taxes are implicitly given as \( {t}_d^A={p}^{\prime}\left({q}_d+{q}_f\right)+{c}_0^{{\prime\prime} }{q}_f\left({\pi}_{df}^f/{V}_{00}\right) \) and \( {t}_f^A=-\left({p}^{\prime }-{c}_f^{{\prime\prime}}\right){q}_f+{p}^{{\prime\prime} }{q}_f^2\left({\pi}_{df}^f-{V}_{00}\right)/{V}_{00} \).

  7. 7.

    One might think that in the absence of tax on the public firm, the government can achieve the same welfare as Regime A by setting an appropriate privatization ratio. However, because the privatization ratio is restricted as \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \), we cannot exclude the possibility of a corner solution.

  8. 8.

    From (6.13), (6.14), and (6.15), we have \( {\left.\partial {q}_d/\partial \theta \right|}_{T_D={T}_D^{*}}=\left[a\left(3+\rho \right)+3{T}_D^{*}\left(1+\rho \right)\right]/{A}^2>0 \) and \( {\left.\partial \left({q}_d+{q}_0\right)/\partial \theta \right|}_{T_D={T}_D^{*}}=-\left[3a\left(3+\rho \right)+3{T}_D^{*}\left(1+\rho \right)\right]/{A}^2<0 \), where \( A\equiv 3\theta +4\rho +3 \).

  9. 9.

    From (6.13), (6.14), and (6.15), we have \( {\left.\partial Q/\partial {t}_f\right|}_{\theta =1}=-\left(\rho +1\right)/\left[2\left(2\rho +3\right)\right] \).

  10. 10.

    For a given θ, the optimal tariff is \( {\tau}_I\left(\theta \right)=\frac{6\rho +7{\rho}^2+\theta \left(9\rho +3\right)+{\theta}^2\left(3\rho +12\right)}{59\rho +41{\rho}^2+\theta \left(66\rho +48\right)+{\theta}^2\left(9\rho +36\right)+21} \). Inserting this expression into (6.13), (6.14), and (6.15), we have \( \partial Q/\partial \theta <0 \) and \( \partial {q}_d/\partial \theta >0 \).

References

  • Brander JA, Spencer BJ (1984) Tariff protection and imperfect competition. In: Kierzkowski H (ed) Monopolistic competition and international trade. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang WW (2005) Optimal trade and privatization policies in an international duopoly with cost asymmetry. J Int Trade Econ Dev 14(1):19–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao C-C, Yu SH (2006) Partial privatization, foreign competition, and optimum tariff. Rev Int Econ 14(1):87–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delbono F, Scarpa C (1995) Upward-sloping reaction functions under quantity competition in mixed oligopolies. Bull Econ Res 47(4):341–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1984) International trade policy for oligopolistic industries. Econ J 94(Suppl):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fjell K, Pal D (1996) A mixed oligopoly in the presence of foreign private firms. Can J Econ 29(3):737–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn FH (1962) The stability of the Cournot oligopoly solution. Rev Econ Stud 29(4):329–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han L (2012) Strategic privatization and trade policies in an international mixed oligopoly. Manch Sch 80(5):580–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen M, Lahiri S (1998) The comparison between destination and origin principles under imperfect competition. J Int Econ 45(2):323–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen M, Lahiri S, Raimondos-Møller P (2002) Tax principles and tax harmonization under imperfect competition: a cautionary example. Eur Econ Rev 46(8):1559–1568

    Google Scholar 

  • Kowalski P, Büge M, Sztajerowska M (2013) State-owned enterprises: trade effects and policy implications. OECD trade policy papers 147. OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k4869ckqk7l-en

  • Lee S-H, Xu L, Chen Z (2013) Competitive privatization and tariff policies in an international mixed duopoly. Manch Sch 81(5):763–779

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (1998) Partial privatization in mixed duopoly. J Public Econ 70(3):473–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mujumdar S, Pal D (1998) Effects of indirect taxation in a mixed oligopoly. Econ Lett 58(2):199–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2012). Competitive neutrality: maintaining a level playing field between public and private business. http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/. Accessed 12 Aug 2015

  • Pal D, White M (1998) Mixed oligopoly, privatization, and strategic trade policy. South Econ J 65(2):264–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solano O, Sennekamp A (2006) Competition provisions in regional trade agreements, OECD trade policy working paper 31. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS, Wang YC, Zhao L (2009) Privatization and efficiency gain in an international mixed oligopoly with asymmetric costs. Jpn Econ Rev 60(4):539–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu R, Lee SH (2011) Optimal trade and privatization policies in an international mixed market. Seoul J Econ 24(1):51–71

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kazuyuki Nakamura .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.6.1 Stability Condition

Consider a simple adjustment process according to the Nash conjecture: both domestic and foreign private firms respond to a change in the output of the public firm. Once the private firms have responded, the public firm adjusts its output subject to the optimal response function. First, regarding the change in the public firm’s output, the outputs of the private firms are adjusted as follows:

$$ \left[\begin{array}{c}\hfill d{q}_d/d{q}_0\hfill \\ {}\hfill d{q}_f/d{q}_0\hfill \end{array}\right]=\frac{1}{1-{\phi}_f^d{\phi}_d^f}\left[\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\phi}_0^d+{\phi}_f^d{\phi}_0^f\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\phi}_0^f+{\phi}_d^f{\phi}_0^d\hfill \end{array}\right]. $$
(A6.1)

Thus, stability requires \( \left|{\phi}_f^d{\phi}_d^f\right|<1 \). In such a case, the optimal response functions of the private firms are given by \( {q}_d={\omega}^d\left({q}_0\right) \) and \( {q}_f={\omega}^f\left({q}_0\right) \). Next, the public firm adjusts its outputs according to the following adjustment process :

$$ {q}_{0\left(t+1\right)}={\phi}^0\left[{\omega}^d\left({q}_{0(t)}\right),{\omega}^f\left({q}_{0(t)}\right)\right], $$
(A6.2)

where a subscript(s) denotes the time period. The approximation of the change in output around the equilibrium (denoted by q *0 ) is represented by

$$ \Delta {q}_{0\left(t+1\right)}=\left({\phi}_d^0{\omega^d}^{\prime }+{\phi}_f^0{\omega^f}^{\prime}\right)\Delta {q}_{0(t)}, $$
(A6.3)

where \( \Delta {q}_{0(s)}\equiv {q}_{0(s)}-{q}_0^{*} \). Thus, \( \left|{\Delta}_2\right|=\left|{\phi}_d^0{\omega^d}^{\prime }+{\phi}_f^0{\omega^f}^{\prime}\right|<1 \) is required for the stability.

1.2 A.6.2 Proof of Lemma 6.2

The effect of the change in the privatization ratio on welfare can be written as

$$ \begin{array}{ll}\frac{\partial W\left(0,\theta \right)}{\partial \theta }& ={\mathbf{w}}_q{\mathbf{D}}^{-1}\mathbf{b}\hfill \\ {}& =\frac{{\left({p}^{\prime}\right)}^2\left({q}_f+{q}_0\right)}{\left(1-{\Delta}_1\right)\left(1-{\Delta}_2\right){V}_{00}}\left[\left({q}_f+{q}_d\right)\left(1+{\phi}_0^f\right){\phi}_0^d+{q}_f\left(1+{\phi}_0^d\right){\phi}_0^f+\left({q}_f+z{q}_0\right)\left(1-{\phi}_f^d{\phi}_d^f\right)\right],\hfill \end{array} $$
(A6.4)

where w q denotes the national marginal benefits of an increase in each firm’s output, which is represented as \( {\left.{\mathbf{w}}_q\right|}_{\mathbf{t}=0}=-{p}^{\prime}\left[{q}_d+{q}_f, {q}_f, {q}_f+{q}_0z\right] \). Identical technologies among private firms imply that in the equilibrium, two private firms have the same level of output, denoted by \( \tilde{q}\left(={q}_d={q}_f\right) \). Thus, the optimal response functions also have same slopes denoted as \( {\tilde{\phi}}_q\left(={\phi}_0^d={\phi}_f^d={\phi}_0^f={\phi}_d^f\right) \). Solving \( \partial W\left(0,\theta \right)/\partial \theta =0 \), we have an implicit form of the optimal privatization ratio \( {\theta}_{-t}^{*} \) as follows:

$$ {\theta}_{-t}^{*}=\left(\frac{-{\tilde{\phi}}_q}{1-{\tilde{\phi}}_q}\right)\left(\frac{3\tilde{q}}{q_0+\tilde{q}}\right). $$
(A6.5)

Under condition (i), because \( \partial {q}_0/\partial \theta <0 \) and \( \partial {q}_i/\partial \theta >0 \) for \( i=d,f \) hold from (6.7), \( {q}_0\ge \tilde{q} \) holds for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \). Thus, if condition (i) is met, \( {\tilde{\phi}}_q/\left(1-{\tilde{\phi}}_q\right)\in \left(0,\ 1/2\right) \) and \( 3\tilde{q}/\left({q}_0+\tilde{q}\right)\in \Big(0,\ 3/2\Big] \). Therefore, \( {\theta}_{-t}^{*}\in \left(0,\ 3/4\right) \) under condition (i). We turn to condition (ii). Linear demand function implies \( {\tilde{\phi}}_q<-1/2 \), where strict inequality follows from the convexity of the cost function. In this case, \( {\tilde{\phi}}_q/\left(1-{\tilde{\phi}}_q\right)\in \left(0,\ 1/3\right) \) and \( 3\tilde{q}/\left({q}_0+\tilde{q}\right)\in \left(0,\ 3\right] \). Thus, \( {\theta}_{-t}^{*}\in \left(0,\ 1\right) \) holds under condition (ii). From (A6.4), it is confirmed that \( \partial W\left(0,0\right)/\partial \theta >0 \) and \( \partial W\left(0,1\right)/\partial \theta <0 \) hold if either condition (i) or (ii) is met.

1.3 A.6.3 Proof of Proposition 6.3

Taking account of the feasibility set, we obtain the optimal tax for the given θ:

$$ {T}_O\left(\theta \right)=-2a{\left({\varLambda}_O\right)}^{-1}\left[3\left(3\rho +8\right){\theta}^2-\left(\rho +3\right)\theta +\left(5\rho +6\right)\rho \right], $$
(A6.6)

where \( {\varLambda}_O\equiv 9\ \left(9\rho +8\right){\theta}^2-6\rho \theta +\left(17\rho +7\right)\rho +9>0 \) for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \). Inserting (A6.6) into (6.16), we can write welfare as \( {W}_O={W}_O\left(\theta \right) \) in which origin-based tax is optimally chosen. The first-order condition for θ is as follows:

$$ \frac{d{W}_O\left(\theta \right)}{d\theta }={a}^2{\left({\varLambda}_O\right)}^{-2}\left(7\theta \rho -8\theta +\rho \right)\left(6\theta \rho -7{\rho}^2+9\right)=0. $$
(A6.7)

Thus, we have two roots: \( {\theta}_O^1=\rho /\left(8-7\rho \right) \) for \( \rho \ne 8/7 \) and \( {\theta}_O^2=\left(7{\rho}^2-9\right)/\left(6\rho \right) \). However, the second-order condition implies that θ 2 O gives the minimum solution. Hence, \( {\theta}_O^{*}={\theta}_O^1 \) for \( \rho \in \left(0,1\right] \). In (A6.7), it is confirmed that \( d{W}_O/d\theta >0 \) holds for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \) and \( \rho \in \left(1,3/\sqrt{7}\right) \). That is, \( {\theta}_O^{*}=1 \) is optimal for \( \rho \in \left(1,\ 3/\sqrt{7}\right) \). For \( \rho \ge 3/\sqrt{7} \), θ 2 O becomes nonnegative and \( {\theta}_O^1\notin \left[0,1\right] \). Thus, θ * O is either zero or unity. A direct calculation yields \( {W}_O(1)-{W}_O(0)>0 \) for \( \rho \in \left(1,\ 1.2956\right) \) and \( {W}_O(1)-{W}_O(0)<0 \) for \( \rho \in \left(1.2957,\infty \right) \). Together with these facts described above, the claims are proved.

1.4 A.6.4 Proof of Proposition 6.6

For the given privatization ratio, the optimal taxes can be written as follows:

$$ {T}_C\left(\theta \right)=-2a{\left({\varLambda}_C\right)}^{-1}\left[3\left(\rho +4\right){\theta}^2-2\left(\rho +1\right)\theta +\left(2\rho +3\right)\rho \right], $$
(A6.8)
$$ {\tau}_C\left(\theta \right)=2a{\left({\varLambda}_C\right)}^{-1}\left[\left(9\rho +12\right){\theta}^2-\left(3\rho +1\right)\theta +\left(3\rho +4\right)\rho \right], $$
(A6.9)

where \( {\varLambda}_C\equiv \left(45\rho +36\right){\theta}^2-6\rho \theta +\left(9\rho +15\right)\rho +5>0 \) for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \). The second-order condition is satisfied because W(T C , τ C , θ) is concave in T C and τ C for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \). Inserting (A6.8) and (A6.9) into (6.10), we can write the welfare as \( {W}_C={W}_C\left(\theta \right) \) in which the taxes are optimally chosen. The first-order condition for θ is as follows:

$$ \frac{d{W}_C\left(\theta \right)}{d\theta }={a}^2{\left({\varLambda}_C\right)}^{-2}\left[\left(3\theta \rho -4\theta +\rho \right)\left(6\theta \rho -3{\rho}^2+5\right)\right]=0. $$
(A6.10)

Although \( {\theta}_C^1=\rho /\left(4-3\rho \right) \) for \( \rho \ne 4/3 \) and \( {\theta}_C^2=\left(3{\rho}^2-5\right)/\left(6\rho \right) \) are two roots of (A6.10), θ 2 C gives a minimum value. Hence, \( {\theta}_C^{*}={\theta}_C^1 \) for \( \rho \in \left(0,1\right] \). In contrast, \( d{W}_C/d\theta >0 \) holds for \( \theta \in \left[0,1\right] \) and \( \rho \in \left(1,\sqrt{5/3}\right) \). That is, \( {\theta}_O^{*}=1 \) is optimal for \( \rho \in \left(1,\sqrt{5/3}\right) \). For \( \rho \ge \sqrt{5/3} \), θ 2 C is nonnegative and \( {\theta}_C^1\notin \left[0,1\right] \): θ * C is either zero or unity. We obtain \( {W}_C(1)-{W}_C(0)>0 \) for \( \rho \in \left(1,\ 1.7183\right] \), and \( {W}_C(1)-{W}_C(0)<0 \) for \( \rho \in \left[1.7184,\infty \right) \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kunizaki, M., Shinozaki, T., Nakamura, K. (2017). Optimal Partial Privatization in an International Mixed Oligopoly Under Various Tax Principles. In: Yanagihara, M., Kunizaki, M. (eds) The Theory of Mixed Oligopoly. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 14. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55633-6_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics