Skip to main content

Tough Love and Intergenerational Altruism

  • Chapter
  • 2479 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter develops and studies a tough love model of intergenerational altruism. We model tough love by modifying the Barro-Becker standard altruism model in two ways. First, the child’s discount factor is endogenously determined, so lower childhood consumption leads to a higher discount factor later in life. Second, the parent evaluates the child’s lifetime utility with a constant high discount factor. Our model predicts that parental transfers will fall when the child’s discount factor falls. This is in contrast with the standard altruism model, which predicts that parental transfers are independent of exogenous changes in the child’s discount factor.

The original article first appeared in the International Economic Review 53, 791–814, 2012. A newly written addendum has been added to this book chapter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Recent theoretical models that adopt the Uzawa-type formulation include Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2003) and Choi et al. (2008).

  2. 2.

    See Caplin and Leahy (2004), Farhi and Werning (2007), Phelan (2006), and Sleet and Sevin (20052007).

  3. 3.

    This chapter focuses on the parent’s role in preference formation. A related work is Mulligan (1998) on the altruistic preference formation of the parent toward the child.

  4. 4.

    In a recent work, Slav́ik and Wiseman (2009, Tough love for lazy kids: dynamic insurance and equal bequests, unpublished manuscript) have also proposed a model of tough love. These authors emphasize the moral hazard problem faced by parents in order to construct a model with a dynamic insurance strategy that involves providing greater inter vivos transfers to poor children and dividing bequests equally. Their model does not involve endogenous time discounting.

  5. 5.

    This issue is related to the literature on the importance of initial endowments on subsequent outcomes of a dynamic process (Heckman 1981, 1991). As suggested by Heckman, it is important to distinguish between heterogeneity (how persistent is the effect of initial endowments on outcomes), and state dependence (whether subsequent experiences attenuate or accentuate the effect of initial endowments). It is possible that a raw correlation between wealth and consumption growth reflects a causal influence of wealth on consumption growth (state dependence), or the fact that individuals differ in time preferences and more patient people accumulate more wealth (heterogeneity).

  6. 6.

    They control the endogeneity problem by analyzing how the discount factor changes with the size of a prize obtained in another experiment.

  7. 7.

    Baumrind (1966) identified three modes of parental control. The first mode is permissive, where parents act as a resource for their children and do not actively involve themselves in shaping the current and future behavior of the child. The second mode is authoritarian, where the parent uses a set standard of conduct that is theologically or religiously motivated and tries to shape and control the child’s behavior with overt use of power. The third mode is authoritative, where the parent actively involves himself/herself in shaping the child’s behavior and attitudes and uses reasoning and discipline to ensure a well-rounded long-term development of the child. The parent affirms the child’s current behavior, separating right from wrong, and also sets standards for the child’s future behavior.

  8. 8.

    For expositional ease, we begin by making the simplifying assumption that these three periods are of equal duration. Note that results presented in this section as well as in Sect. 4 are robust to varying durations for the three periods. Further, in Sect. 5 we relax this assumption and study the model with varying durations for childhood, work, and retirement.

  9. 9.

    Given the timing of our model, this implies that transfers, T, are made only in period 1. Further, we assume that transfers are made from the parent to the child and there are no reverse transfers.

  10. 10.

    In this simple consumption good economy, we view consumption as a composite good that may include leisure activities such as TV time, video game time etc. In Sect. 5, we extend this basic setup and introduce leisure as a second good.

  11. 11.

    u(.) is continuously differentiable with a nonzero Jacobian.

  12. 12.

    Note that changes in the parent’s own discount factor will affect transfers. However, here we are imagining a sudden change in social norms that affects only the child’s discount factor with no effect on the parent’s discount factor.

  13. 13.

    The discussion presented here postulates a model of parental tough love in the context of a single generation. An interesting extension is to model tough love in a dynastic framework exemplified in the context of the standard altruism model by Barro (1974). In such a model, the child will be a repeater in the dynamic process and will pass on the discount factor she inherited from her tough love parent to her own offspring. We are investigating the implications of such a framework for tough love altruism in a separate paper that is a work in progress (Bhatt et al. 2011).

  14. 14.

    It can be easily shown that

    $$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} <0\;\ \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T}> 0& & {}\\ \end{array}$$
  15. 15.

    Note that since \(\frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}}\) is strictly positive for β p  = β 3, k , we have a positive relationship between T and β 0 even when β p  < β 3, k , as long as the difference is small in magnitude.

  16. 16.

    Our simulation results are robust to alternative parametric specifications of the utility function and also to a wide range of model parameter values.

  17. 17.

    We have chosen our parameter values to be consistent with consensus estimates reported in the literature. When such estimates are not available, we have used the optimality conditions of our model and used micro data to approximate the parameter values. For σ, we are using a value of 1.5, which implies an elasticity of intertemporal substitution of around 0.67. In the literature, many studies have used micro data and have estimated this parameter to be between 0.4 and 0.7 (see Hall 2009; Ogaki and Reinhart 1998). For deriving a value for η, given our parametric specification and under the assumption that β p and β k are approximately close to each other, from the parent’s first-order condition we obtain:

    $$\displaystyle{\frac{C_{p}^{-\sigma }} {C_{1}^{-\sigma }} = \frac{1-\eta } {\eta }.}$$

    We used σ = 1. 5 and data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) on per capita annual consumption expenditure for individuals aged 25 or below to approximate C 1. We used per capita annual consumption expenditure for individuals aged 65 or above to approximate C p . Then, the above optimality condition η = 0. 66. Finally, for parameter a, we assumed a value of 0.02, although we also tried alternative values of 0.01 and 0.04 and found that the results are robust to these alternative values for parameter a.

  18. 18.

    We have also studied the version of our model where we add the bequest motive for the parent. We find that the main result of the paper remains qualitatively unchanged. Consistent with our intuition of parental tough love, the parent with a tough love motive respond to a fall in his child’s discount factor by reducing transfers and increasing bequests. In contrast, the parent in the standard altruism model increase transfers and decrease bequests in response to a fall in the child’s discount factor.

  19. 19.

    For brevity, we have not provided proofs for the redistributive neutrality property for all the models presented in this chapter. These analytical results are available from the authors upon request.

  20. 20.

    Using data from the Health and Retirement Survey (HRS), McGarry (1999) found a positive relationship between the recipient’s permanent income and the amount of transfers. However, this study uses education of the respondent as a proxy for the permanent income, which may be missing important aspects of permanent income. Further, when estimating the relationship between the recipient’s permanent income and amount of transfers, McGarry (1999) did not adjust the parent’s permanent income in order to keep family permanent income constant. We believe that the Altonji et al. (1997) result is more robust as they used better measures of permanent incomes of the parent and the child and also controlled for family permanent income when evaluating the relationship between recipients’ permanent income and their transfers.

  21. 21.

    For simplicity, we abstract from the child’s early life in which he does not face the work–leisure choice.

  22. 22.

    Cunha et al. (2006) present a survey of empirical evidence that later interventions in adolescent years can affect noncognitive skills such as patience, self-control, temperament, time preferences, etc., while these interventions cannot affect cognitive skills.

  23. 23.

    We thank an anonymous referee for bringing this point to our notice as a potential future work.

References

  • Akabayashi H (2006) An equilibrium model of child maltreatment. J Econ Dyn Control 30:993–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji GJ (1986) Intertemporal substitution in labor supply: evidence from micro data. J Politi Econ 94:1121–1166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji GJ, Hayashi F, Kotlikoff JL (1997) Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: theory and evidence. J Politi Econ 105:1121–1166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkeson A, Ogaki M (1996) Wealth-varying intertemporal elasticities of substitution: evidence from panel and aggregate data. J Monet Econ 38:507–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro JR (1974) Are government bonds new wealth? J Politi Econ 82:1095–1117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumrind D (1966) Effects of authoritative parental control on child behavior. Child Dev 37:887–907

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1974) A theory of social interactions. J Politi Econ 82:1063–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G, Mulligan CB (1997) The endogenous determination of time preference. Q J Econ 112:1063–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V (2011) Adolescent alcohol use and intergenerational transfers: evidence from micro data. J Fam Econ Issues 32:296–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V, Ogaki M (2009) Tough love, intergenerational altruism, and worldviews. J Behav Econ Finance 2:1–6

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V, Ogaki M (2012) Tough love and intergenerational altruism. Int Econ Rev 53:791–814

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V, Nakajima T, Ogaki M (2011) Tough love with an infinite horizon (work in progress)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V, Ogaki M, Yaguchi Y (2013) Normative behavioral economics based on unconditional love and moral virtue. Paper presented at 10th biennial Pacific rim conference, Tokyo. Western Economic Association International

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt V, Ogaki M, Yaguchi Y (2014) A reformulation of normative economics for models with endogenous preferences. Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2001) The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. J Econ Theory 97:298–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2011) The economics of cultural transmission and socialization. In: Jess Benhabib AB, Jackson MO (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1A. Elsevier/North-Holland, Boston, pp 339–416

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, MaCurdy TE (1999) Labor supply: a review of alternative approaches. In: Aschenfleter Q, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1559–1695

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruni L, Sugden R (2013) Market reasoning as moral reasoning: why economists should re-engage with political philosophy. J Econ Perspect 27:141–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplin A, Leahy J (2004) The social discount rate. J Politi Econ 112:1257–1268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson L, Grossbart S (1988) Parental style and consumer socialization of children. J Consum Res 15:77–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castaneda A, Diaz-Gimenez J, Rios-Rull JV (2003) Accounting for the U.S. earnings and wealth inequality. J Politi Econ 111:818–857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi H, Mark NC, Sul D (2008) Endogenous discounting, the world saving glut and the U.S. current account. J Int Econ 75:30–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1987) Motives for private income transfers. J Politi Econ 95:508–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunha F, James H, Lochner L, Masterov DV (2006) Interpreting the evidence on life cycle skill formation. In: Hanushek EA, Stephen M, Ludger W (eds) Handbook of the economics of education. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 697–812

    Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M, Zilibotti F (2008) Occupational choice and the spirit of capitalism. Q J Econ 123:747–793

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen JT, Falk A, Huffman D, Sunde U (2008) The intergenerational transmission of risk and trust attitudes, iZA Research Paper Series, Working Paper No. 2380

    Google Scholar 

  • Farhi E, Werning I (2007) Inequality and social discounting. J Politi Econ 115:365–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez R, Fogli A, Olivetti C (2004) Mothers and sons: preference formation and female labor force dynamics. Q J Econ 119:1249–1299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) The theory of interest. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • French E (2004) The labor supply response to (mismeasured but) predictable wage changes. Rev Econ Stat 86:602–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE (2009) Reconciling cyclical movements in the marginal value of time and the marginal product of labor. J Politi Econ 117:281–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ham JC, Reilly KT (2006) Using micro data to estimate the intertemporal substitution elasticity for labor supply in an implicit contract model, iEPR Working Paper No. 06.54

    Google Scholar 

  • Hao L, Hotz VJ, Jin GZ (2008) Games parents and adolescents play: risky behavior, parental reputation and strategic transfers. Econ J 118:515–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ (1981) Heterogeneity and state dependence. In: Rosen S (ed) Studies in labor markets. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 91–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirata K, Hirokuni I, Kazuo H, Shinsuke I, Yoshiro T, Ohtake F (2010a) Genetic inheritance of time-discounting behavior: a Bayesian approach using Markov chain Monte Carlo method. In: 2010 Japanese Economic Association Spring Meeting, Chiba

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirata K, Iiboshi H, Hayakawa K, Ikeda S, Tsutsui Y, Ohtake F (2010b) Genetic inheritance of time-discounting behavior: a Bayesian approach using Markov chain Monte Carlo method. Paper presented at the 2010 Japanese Economic Association Spring Meeting, Chiba University, Chiba

    Google Scholar 

  • Horioka CY (2002) Are the Japanese selfish, altruistic or dynastic? Jpn Econ Rev 53:26–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ida T, Goto R (2009) Simultaneous measurement of time and risk preferences: stated discrete choice modeling analysis depending on smoking behavior. Int Econ Rev 50:1169–1182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda S, Ohtake F, Yoshiro T (2005) Time discount rates: an analysis based on economic experiments and questionnaire surveys. Institute of Social and Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 638, Osaka University

    Google Scholar 

  • Kagel JH, Battalio RC, Green L (1995) Economic choice theory: an experimental analysis of animal behavior. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krusell P, Smith AA (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. J Politi Econ 106:867–896

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kubota K, Horioka CY, Kamesaka A, Ogaki M, Ohtake F (2009) Tough love and intergenerational altruism in U.S. and Japanese surveys (unpublished manuscript)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kubota K, Horioka CY, Kamesaka A, Ogaki M, Ohtake F (2011, forthcoming) Worldviews and tough love. J Behav Econ Finance

    Google Scholar 

  • Kubota K, Kamesaka A, Ogaki M, Ohtake F (2013) Cultures, worldviews, and intergenerational altruism. Paper presented at the European regional science association 2013 congress, Palermo

    Google Scholar 

  • Laitner J, Juster T (1996) New evidence on altruism: a study of TIAA-CREF retirees. Am Econ Rev 86:893–908

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrance EC (1991) Poverty and the rate of time preference: evidence from panel data. J Politi Econ 99:54–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MaCurdy T (1981) An empirical model of labor supply in a life-cycle setting. J Politi Econ 89:1059–1085

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maital S (1982) Minds, markets and money. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • McGarry K (1999) Inter vivos transfers and intended bequests. J Publ Econ 73:321–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mischel W (1961) Father-absence and delay of gratification: cross-cultural comparisons. J Abnorm Soc Psychol 63:116–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogaki M, Atkeson A (1997) Rate of time preference, intertemporal elasticity of substitution, and level of wealth. Rev Econ Stat 79:564–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogaki M, Reinhart CM (1998) Intertemporal substitution and durable goods: long-run data. Econ Lett 61:85–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa K (1993) Economic development and time preference schedule: the case of Japan and East Asian NICs. J Dev Econ 42:175–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelan C (2006) Opportunity and social mobility. Rev Econ Stud 73:487–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose GM, Dalakas V, Kropp F (2003) Consumer socialization and parental style across cultures: findings from Australia, Greece, and India. J Consum Psychol 13:366–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandel MJ (2009) Justice: what’s the right thing to do? Farrar Straus & Giroux, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandel MJ (2012) What money can’t buy: the moral limits of markets. Farrar Straus & Giroux, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandel MJ (2013) Market reasoning as moral reasoning: why economists should re-engage with political philosophy. J Econ Perspect 27:121–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2003) Closing small open economy models. J Int Econ 44:257–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sleet C, Sevin Y (2005) Social credibility, social patience, and long-run inequality. Manuscript, Carnegie Mellon University

    Google Scholar 

  • Sleet C, Sevin Y (2007) Credibility and endogenous societal discounting. Rev Econ Dyn 9:410–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1968) Time preference, the consumption function, and optimum asset holdings. In: Wolfe JN (ed) Value, capital, and growth: papers in honour of Sir John Hicks. University of Edinburgh Press, Edinburgh

    Google Scholar 

  • Webley P, Nyhus E (2006) Parent’s influence on children’s future orientation and saving. J Econ Psychol 27:140–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinberg AB (2001) An incentive model of the effect of parental income on children. J Politi Econ 109:266–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Shinsuke Ikeda for his initial collaboration, Dean Lillard for comments and discussions from the initial stage of this research, three anonymous referees, Fumio Hayashi, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki; and seminar and session participants at the 2008 North American Summer Econometric Society, Midwest Economics, and Midwest Macroeconomics Meetings; Aoyama Gakuin, Baskent, Bilkent, Doshisha, Fukuoka, Hiroshima, Hitotsubashi, Keio, Kobe, Koc, Kyoto, Nagoya, Nihon, Ohio State, Osaka, Osaka Prefecture, Sabanci, Waseda, Yale Universities; and the Universities of Cyprus and Tokyo for comments. This research of Masao Ogaki was partially supported by Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research from Japan Society for the Promotion of Science.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masao Ogaki .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 A Proof for Proposition 1

In this section of the appendix we provide an analytical proof of our main result specified in Eq. (2.13):

$$ \displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} \!\!>\!\! 0\ \ \mathit{iff }\ \ {\biggl [1 + R(\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} {u^{{\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} - (\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} \biggr ]}> 0.& & {}\\ \end{array} $$

We start the derivation of the above result by noting that the parent accounts for C 2 when maximizing utility by choosing transfers, T. From the first-order condition for the parent’s problem described in Eqs. (2.10) and (2.11), we obtain:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} V ^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ p} - T^{{\ast}}),\tilde{\beta })& =& {}\\ & & {\biggl (\frac{1-\eta } {\eta } \biggr )} \frac{\tilde{\beta }} {R}{\biggl (u^{{\prime}}(y_{ 1} + T^{{\ast}})\! +\!\beta _{ p}u^{{\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} -\beta _{p}^{2}Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggr )},{}\\ \end{array}$$

where T denotes optimal parental transfers, \(V ^{{\prime}}(.) = \frac{\partial V (.)} {\partial T}\), and \(u^{{\prime}}(.) = \frac{\partial u(.)} {\partial T}.\)

Now consider an exogenous change in the child’s discount factor (β k ) captured by a change in β 0. From the parent’s first-order condition described above we obtain:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} = A {\ast}{\biggl ( \frac{\partial } {\partial \beta _{0}}{\biggl [\beta _{p}u^{{\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} -\beta _{p}^{2}Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggr ]}\biggr )},& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

where:

$$\displaystyle{A = - \frac{{\biggl (\frac{1-\eta } {\eta } \biggr )}\tilde{\beta }} {V ^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{p} - T^{{\ast}}),\tilde{\beta }) +{\biggl ( \frac{1-\eta } {\eta } \biggr )}\tilde{\beta }u^{{\prime\prime}}(y_{1} + T^{{\ast}})}.}$$

Given concavity of V(.) and u(.), we know that A > 0. Hence:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \mathit{sign}{\biggl (\frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} \biggr )} = \mathit{sign}{\biggl ( \frac{\partial } {\partial \beta _{0}}{\biggl [\beta _{p}u^{{\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} -\beta _{p}^{2}Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggr ]}\biggr )}.& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

Then \(\frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}}> 0\) if and only if:

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\partial } {\partial \beta _{0}}{\biggl [\beta _{p}u^{{\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} -\beta _{p}^{2}Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggr ]}> 0.}$$

Now using the first-order condition for the child’s problem, we can rewrite the above condition as follows.

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial } {\partial \beta _{0}}{\biggl [ - (\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggr ]}> 0& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

It is straightforward to show that the LHS of the above expression is given by:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} \biggl (1 + R(\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} {u^{{\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} {}\\ & & \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad - (\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} \biggr ). {}\\ \end{array}$$

Since \(\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T}> 0\) and u (. ) > 0, the above expression is strictly positive if and only if:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} {\biggl [1 + R(\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} {u^{{\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} - (\beta _{p} -\beta _{3,k})\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} \biggr ]}> 0& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

This establishes our claim in Eq. (2.14). Now, given positive marginal utility, concavity of u(. ), and \(\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} <0\), the sufficient conditions for the above expression to be strictly positive are:

  1. (i)

    β p  ≥ β 3, k and

  2. (ii)

    \(\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} \leq 0\).

1.2 A Proof for Proposition 2

In this section we show that \(\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} \leq 0\) will depend on the convexity of the marginal utility (as captured by the positive third derivative of the utility function) and the impatience level of the child.

We start our derivation with the partial derivative of the optimal second period consumption with respect to parental transfers:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial T} = \frac{\beta ^{{\prime}}(y_{1} + T)Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))} {[u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{2}^{{\ast}}) +\beta _{3,k}R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))]},& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

where

$$\displaystyle{\beta _{3,k} =\beta _{0} +\psi (y_{1} + T).}$$

Differentiating with respect to β 0

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T} = \frac{N} {D},& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

where

$$\displaystyle{D = [u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}}) +\beta _{ 3,k}R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))]^{2}> 0.}$$

and

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} N = [u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}}) +\beta _{ 3,k}R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))][-\psi ^{{\prime}}(y_{ 1} + T)R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} ]& & {}\\ -\psi ^{{\prime}}(y_{ 1} + T)Ru^{{\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))[u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} + R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}() -\beta _{ 3,k}R^{3}u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} ].& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

Since, D is always positive, the sign of \(\frac{\partial ^{2}C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}\partial T}\) depends on the sign of N. Now, the sign of N will be the same as the sign of:

$$\displaystyle{\mathit{sign}([u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} + R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}})) -\beta _{ 3,k}R^{3}u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}))\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} ]).}$$

If the above expression is negative then N < 0.

Hence, the condition for N < 0 is:

$$\displaystyle{[u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{ 2}^{{\ast}})\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} + R^{2}u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{ 3}^{{\ast}})\{1 - (\beta _{ 3,k}R\frac{u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} {u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} \}] <0.}$$

The above condition holds if,

  1. (i)

    \(u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(.) \geq 0\) and

  2. (ii)

    \(\beta _{3,k}\ R\ G \leq 1\),

where

$$\displaystyle{G ={\biggl ( \frac{u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} {u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} \biggr )}\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}}.}$$

1.3 Power Utility Function

In this section of the appendix we use the power utility function to interpret the following condition:

$$\displaystyle{\beta _{3,k}\ R\ G \leq 1,}$$

where

$$\displaystyle{G ={\biggl ( \frac{u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} {u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} \biggr )}\frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}}.}$$

We assume that the period utility function is given by:

$$\displaystyle{u(c) = \frac{c^{1-\sigma }} {1-\sigma }.}$$

Using the above specification of the utility function, from the child’s optimization problem, we get:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} C_{2}^{{\ast}} = \frac{\mathit{Ry}_{2}} {R + (\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }} & & {}\\ \end{array}$$
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} C_{3}^{{\ast}} = R(y_{ 2} - C_{2}^{{\ast}}) = (\beta _{ 3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }C_{2}^{{\ast}}& & {}\\ \end{array}$$
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial C_{2}^{{\ast}}} {\partial \beta _{0}} = -\frac{R^{2}y_{2}(\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1-\sigma } {\sigma } }} {\sigma [R + (\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }]^{2}}& & {}\\ \end{array}$$
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{u^{{\prime\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} {u^{{\prime\prime}}(C_{3}^{{\ast}})} = -(\sigma +1)(\beta _{3,k}R)^{-\frac{1} {\sigma } }{\biggl ( \frac{R + (\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }} {\mathit{Ry}_{2}} \biggr )}& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

Hence, for the power utility case we get:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} G ={\biggl ( \frac{\sigma +1} {\sigma } \biggr )} \frac{1} {\beta _{3,k}[R + (\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }]}& & {}\\ \end{array}$$

Using the above expression for G we can rewrite the inequality of interest as:

$$\displaystyle{\beta _{3,k}R{\biggl (\frac{\sigma +1} {\sigma } \biggr )} \frac{1} {\beta _{3,k}[R + (\beta _{3,k}R)^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }]} \leq 1}$$

Rearranging, we get the following condition:

$$\displaystyle{\beta _{3,k}R \leq {\biggl ( \frac{\sigma } {R}\biggr )}^{\frac{1} {\sigma } }}$$

Addendum: Recent Developments

This addendum has been newly written for this book chapter.

Two directions of research that are closely related to the tough love model have been developing since the working paper version (Bhatt and Ogaki 2008) of this chapter was published. One direction is for normative economics and the other is for positive economics. The first direction is to add an element of virtue ethics to welfarism that has been the basis of normative economics. The second direction is to empirically evaluate the tough love model.

In Bhatt et al. (2014), we proposed an approach of normative economics for models with endogenous preferences that adds an element of virtue ethics to the traditional formulation based on the Bergson-Samuelson social welfare function (SWF). Our approach is based on the moral evaluation function (MEF) that evaluates different endogenous preferences in terms of moral virtue and on the social objective function (SOF), which is a function of SWF and MEF in order to express a balanced value judgment. This is in a sense a response to Sandel’s (2013) call to introduce more value judgment into economics based on his ideas of political philosophy explained for wide audience in Sandel (20092012). In the same issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives as in Sandel (2013) and Bruni and Sugden (2013) argued that neoclassical economics has already incorporated virtue ethics if we think about market virtues. Our approach can incorporate market virtues, but can also incorporate other virtues such as altruism toward a disabled stranger as shown in Bhatt et al. (2014). In Bhatt and Ogaki (2014, Rational addiction and optimal taxation: a reexamination based on the social objective function, unpublished), we applied our approach to the rational addiction model. If a society finds that preferences with drug addiction caused by past drug consumption is less virtuous, preferences affected by drug addiction are less virtuous than preferences that are not.

For the purpose of illustrating our approach by an example, Bhatt et al. (2013) applies it to a version of Bhatt and Ogaki’s tough love model. In this version, the original model is extended by bequest and bequest tax. In the model, the parent thinks that he should not spoil the child so that the child will grow to be patient, but is tempted to spoil the child because he enjoys watching his child having higher childhood utility. With a bequest motive, the parent can use the money saved by lowering childhood transfers in order to increase his bequest given to the child after she grows up. In this version of the model, the government has a policy tool of the bequest tax rate that can be used to influence the optimizing behaviors of the parent and the child. When the bequest tax rate is higher, the parent is more tempted to spoil the child because the money he saves by giving less transfers to the child will be taxed away when he gives the bequest.

If our informal discussions with many economists give a good guidance, many economists seem to think that moral value ethics is not desirable for public policy evaluations because they do not want the government to influence people’s preferences. However, in our model, the government does influence the child’s preferences as long as the bequest tax rate is not zero. The optimum tax rate is positive when the SWF is maximized. On the other hand, the optimum tax rate is zero when the SOF is maximized with α = 0. 3. Thus, introducing moral virtue ethics may result in a policy that does not affect people’s preferences. This illustrates that introduction of moral virtue ethics does not necessarily mean that the government starts to influence people’s preferences. Because any government policy may be influencing people’s preferences even when the government does not intentionally do so, it seems important to examine how each policy is influencing people’s preferences and think about how desirable such influences are for the society.

This line of thoughts leads us to the second direction of research. In order to examine whether or not any policy is influencing people’s preferences, we need empirical work on models with endogenous preferences in which such policy can affect preferences. For the tough love model with the bequest tax rate, there already exit some empirical work. A starting point of any model with endogenous time discounting is that genetic factors do not completely determine time discounting. Using a unique data set of twins in Japan, Hirata et al. (2010) found empirical evidence in favor of this.

Kubota et al. (2013) examined how parents’ tendencies for tough love behavior depend on various measures of time discounting for parents’ own lending and borrowing over different time horizons. Using the Osaka University Global COE survey data for Japan and the United States, they found evidence that is consistent with the tough love model. They also found one empirical puzzle that proportionately more U.S. parents show tough love to young children before the school age than Japanese parents even after controlling for time discounting and other economic and demographic factors. The is especially puzzling because more patient parents tend to show tough love, and Japanese parents are estimated by Kubota et al. (2013) to be more patient than U.S. parents.

Kubota et al. (2013, Time discounting and intergenerational altruism, unpublished) examined a possible solution to this puzzle is cultural differences between the two countries. They used a framework in anthropology that a worldview is behind each culture. Using the Osaka University Global COE survey data for Japan and the United States, they found that differences in the distributions of the confidence in worldview beliefs can explain a substantial portion of the international differences in the parental attitudes.

Akabayashi et al. (2014) reported evidence that is more consistent with the tough love model than with the standard Barro-Becker model from experiments with parent-child pairs. In their time preference experiments, each parent-child pair makes individual and joint decisions about how much and when the child receives a payment (e.g., 1,000 yen now versus 1,001 yen in 2 months). The Barro-Becker model in which the parent does not know the child’s time discount rate predicts that the only reason for the parent to make a different decision from the child when s/he makes an individual decision is the lack of knowledge about the child’s time discount factor. Hence the joint decision is predicted to be the same as the child’s individual decision. However, they find that about half of the pairs do not follow this prediction.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bhatt, V., Ogaki, M. (2016). Tough Love and Intergenerational Altruism. In: Ikeda, S., Kato, H., Ohtake, F., Tsutsui, Y. (eds) Behavioral Interactions, Markets, and Economic Dynamics. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55501-8_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics