Skip to main content

Interdependency Among Addictive Behaviours and Time/Risk Preferences: Discrete Choice Model Analysis of Smoking, Drinking, and Gambling

  • Chapter
Book cover Behavioral Economics of Preferences, Choices, and Happiness

Abstract

This chapter simultaneously measures the rate of time preference and the coefficient of risk aversion, as well as investigates the interdependencies of four addictive behaviours: smoking, drinking, pachinko (a popular Japanese form of pinball gambling), and horse betting among a sample of the Japanese population. We reach two main conclusions. First, there are significant interdependencies among the four addictive behaviours, in particular between smoking and drinking and between gambling on pachinko and the horses. Second, we conclude that the higher the time preference rate and the lower the risk aversion coefficient becomes, the more likely individuals smoke, drink frequently, and gamble on pachinko and the horses.

The original article first appeared in Journal of Economic Psychology 30(4):608–621, 2009. A newly written addendum has been added to this book chapter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See DiClemente and Hantula (2003) as to a review of the applied behavioural literature in consumer choice.

  2. 2.

    It would be interesting to extend the analysis to ‘beneficial addiction’ (d[\( \partial \)U/\( \partial \)ci]/dS > 0) including jogging and swimming. There is some controversy as to whether jogging and swimming can be also considered addictions (Holden 2001); excessive exercise can cause unhealthy outcomes (McKenzie 1999) and can also be a harmful addiction in this case.

  3. 3.

    Some research found the opposite: smokers exhibited lower discount rates (Chesson and Viscusi 2000).

  4. 4.

    A few studies have tried to integrate the measurements of time and risk preferences. Examples include Rachlin et al. (1991), Keren and Roelofsma (1995), Anderhub et al. (2001), and Yi et al. (2006).

  5. 5.

    In health economics, obtaining reveal preference (RP) data is sometimes difficult, since the market is incomplete; it is advantageous to utilize stated preference (SP) data using experiments and questionnaire surveys. As such, this hypothetical technique has been applied in healthcare settings, and previous results have revealed that SP results have internal validity and consistency (Viney et al. 2002).

  6. 6.

    They interestingly discovered that the rate of time preference was robust with respect to the different assumptions regarding habit formation, while the coefficient of relative risk aversion changed substantially across specifications.

  7. 7.

    In pachinko, the object is to increase the number of pachinko balls to exchange for cash or prizes.

  8. 8.

    Tsuge et al. (2005) is interesting because it applies the DCE analysis of risk preference.

  9. 9.

    In our survey, a respondent was told that when choosing Alternative 2, which included delay and risk, she first drew lots; when a winning number was drawn, she would get a prize after a given period of time.

  10. 10.

    As is commonly known, the exponential discounted utility model was advocated by Samuelson (1937) and axiomatically defined by Koopmans (1960) and Fishburn and Rubinstein (1982). The expected utility model is attributed to von Neumann and Morgenstern (1953).

  11. 11.

    If we consider index s the state of nature, s = 1,…,S, expected utility is written as Σ s=1,…,S probabilitys*utility(rewards). Note that we simply assume here that one alternative has only one state of nature other than the state of zero reward.

  12. 12.

    This is partly because both the constant rate of time preference and the coefficient of relative risk aversion still provide good benchmarks.

  13. 13.

    ML models are also called random parameter models if focusing on the distribution of parameters, or error component models if focusing on flexible substitution patterns (Revelt and Train 1998; Brownstone and Train 1999).

  14. 14.

    Louviere et al. (2000, p. 201) suggest that 100 replications are normally sufficient for a typical problem involving five alternatives, 1,000 observations, and up to 10 attributes (Revelt and Train 1998). The adoption of the Halton sequence draw is an important problem to be examined (Halton 1960). Bhat (2001) found that 100 Halton sequence draws are more efficient than 1,000 random draws for simulating ML models.

  15. 15.

    Louviere et al. (2000, pp. 142–143) showed that the variance is an inverse function of the scale as \( {\sigma}^2={\pi}^2/6{\alpha}^2 \). Therefore, the associated variance σ 2 becomes 1.645.

  16. 16.

    It is not necessarily a long-established hypothesis that smoking is positively correlated with impulsive delay discounting. Famous research by Fuchs (1982) reported weak relations between them, for example.

  17. 17.

    Our finding that social drinking exhibited more self-control than no drinking was predicted by Ainslie (2001) and Rachlin (2004).

  18. 18.

    The correction of the asymptotic covariance matrix at the second step requires some additional computation (Murphy and Topel 1985).

  19. 19.

    Whether addiction is intertemporally rational or irrational depends on whether choice is time-consistent or time-inconsistent. Several studies have regarded addiction as time-inconsistent behaviour. For example, Gruber and Koszegi (2001) demonstrated that preferences with respect to smoking were time inconsistent; individuals both failed to recognize the true difficulty of quitting and sought self-control devices to help them quit. Kan (2007) empirically studied time-inconsistent preferences in the context of cigarette smoking behaviour and concluded that a smoker who wanted to quit had a demand for control devices, e.g., a smoking ban in public areas or a hike in cigarette taxes.

  20. 20.

    Mitchell (1999) and Reynolds et al. (2003) reported negligible correlations between them.

References

  • Ainslie G (2001) Breakdown of will. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof G (1991) Procrastination and obedience. Am Econ Rev 81:1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Alessi SM, Petry NM (2003) Pathological gambling severity is associated with impulsivity in a delay discounting procedure. Behav Process 64:345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderhub V, Guth W, Gneezy U, Sonsino D (2001) On the interaction of risk and time preferences: an experimental study. Ger Econ Rev 2:239–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker F, Johnson MW, Bickel WK (2003) Delay discounting in current and never-before cigarette smokers: similarities and differences across commodity, sign, and magnitude. J Abnorm Psychol 112:382–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barsky RB, Juster FT, Kimball MS, Shapiro MT (1997) Preference parameters and behavioral heterogeneity: an experimental approach in the health and retirement study. Q J Econ 112:537–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) A theory of rational addiction. J Polit Econ 96:675–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Rangel A (2005) Behavioral public economics: welfare and policy analysis with non-standard decision makers, NBER working paper, #11518. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bhat C (2001) Quasi-random maximum simulated likelihood estimation of the mixed multinomial logit model. Transp Res B 35:677–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bickel WK, Marsch LA (2001) Toward a behavioral economic understanding of drug dependence: delay discounting processes. Addiction 96:73–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bickel WK, Odum AL, Madden GJ (1999) Impulsivity and cigarette smoking: delay discounting in current never, and ex-smokers. Psychopharmacology 146:447–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blondel S, Lohéac Y, Rinaudo S (2007) Rationality and drug use: an experimental approach. J Health Econ 26:643–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks J, Cameron AC, Carter CA (1998) Political action committee contributions and U.S. congressional voting on sugar legislation. Am J Agric Econ 80:441–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brownstone D, Train KE (1999) Forecasting new product penetration with flexible substitution patterns. J Econ 89:109–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson RT, Louviere JJ, Anderson DA, Arabie P, Bunch DS, Hensher DA, Johnson RM, Kuhfeld WF, Steinberg D, Swait J, Timmermans H, Wiley JB (1994) Experimental analysis of choice. Mark Lett 5:351–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesson H, Viscusi WK (2000) The heterogeneity of time-risk tradeoffs. J Behav Decis Mak 13:251–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiClemente DF, Hantula DA (2003) Applied behavior economics and consumer choice. J Econ Psychol 24:589–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donkers B, van Soet A (1999) Subjective measures of household preferences and financial decisions. J Econ Psychol 20:613–642

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans WN, Schwab RM (1995) Finishing high school and starting college: Do catholic make a difference? Q J Econ 110:941–974

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans WN, Oates WE, Schwab RM (1992) Measuring peer effects: a study of teenage behavior. J Polit Econ 100:966–991

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn PC, Rubinstein A (1982) Time preference. Int Econ Rev 23:677–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick S, Lowenstein G, O’Donoghue T (2002) Time discounting and time preference; a critical review. J Econ Lit 40:351–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuchs V (1982) Time preferences and health: an exploratory study. In: Fuchs V (ed) Economics aspects of health. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Glantz S, Gonzalez M (2012) Effective tobacco control is key to rapid progress in reduction of non-communicable diseases. Lancet 379:1269–1271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goto R, Nishimura S, Ida T (2007) Discrete choice experiment of smoking cessation behaviour in Japan. Tob Control 6:336–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goto R, Takahashi Y, Ida T (2011) Changes of smokers’ attitudes to intended cessation attempts in Japan. Value Health 14:785–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green L, Myerson J (2004) A discounting framework for choice with delayed and probabilistic rewards. Psychol Bull 130:769–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J, Koszegi B (2001) Is addiction “rational”? Theory and evidence. Q J Econ 116:1261–1303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halton J (1960) On the efficiency of evaluating certain quasi-random sequences of points in evaluating multi-dimensional integrals. Numer Math 2:84–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hensher DA, Rose JM, Greene WH (2005) Applied choice analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Holden C (2001) ‘Behavioral’ addictions: do they exist? Science 294:980–982

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda N, Inoue M, Iso H, Ikeda S, Satoh T, Noda M et al (2012) Adult mortality attributable to preventable risk factors for non-communicable diseases and injuries in Japan: a comparative risk assessment. PLoS Med 9(1):e1001160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kan K (2007) Cigarette smoking and self-control. J Health Econ 26:61–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapteyn A, Teppa F (2003) Hypothetical intertemporal consumption choices. Econ J 113:140–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keren G, Roelofsma P (1995) Immediacy and certainty in intertemporal choice. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 63:287–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans TC (1960) Stationary ordinal utility and impatience. Econometrica 28:287–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Louviere JJ, Hensher DA, Swait JD (2000) Stated choice methods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Madden GJ, Petry NM, Bodger GJ, Bickel WK (1997) Impulsive and self-control choices in opioid-dependendent patients and non-drug-using control participants: drug and monetary rewards. Exp Clin Psychopharmacol 5:256–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madden GJ, Bickel WK, Jacobs EA (1999) Discounting of delayed rewards in opioid-dependent outpatients: exponential or hyperbolic discounting function? Exp Clin Psychopharmacol 7:284–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madden PA, Bucholz KK, Martin NG, Heath AC (2000) Smoking and the genetic contribution to alcohol-dependence risk. Alcohol Res Health 24:209–214

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D, Train KE (2000) Mixed MNL models of discrete choice models of discrete response. J Appl Econ 15:447–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie DC (1999) Markers of excessive exercise. Can J Appl Physiol 24:66–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messinis G (1999) Habit formation and the theory of addiction. J Econ Surv 13:417–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell SH (1999) Measures of impulsivity in cigarette smokers and non-smokers. Psychopharmacology 146:455–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy KM, Topel RH (1985) Estimation and inference in two-step econometric models. J Bus Econ Stat 3:370–379

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson F, Olson L (1978) Specification and estimation of a simultaneous-equation model with limited dependent variables. Int Econ Rev 19:695–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odum AL, Madden GJ, Bickel WK (2002) Discounting of delayed health gains and losses by current, never- and ex-smokers of cigarettes. Nicotine Tob Res 4:295–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohmura Y, Takahashi T, Kitamura N (2005) Discounting delayed and probabilistic monetary gains and losses by smokers of cigarettes. Psychopharmacology 182:508–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides A, Zervos D (1995) Rational addiction with learning and regret. J Polit Econ 103:739–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides A, Zervos D (1998) Myopia and addictive behaviour. Econ J 108:75–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petry NM (2001) Pathological gamblers, with and without substance use disorders, discount delayed rewards at high rates. J Abnorm Psychol 110:482–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petry NM, Casarella T (1999) Excessive discounting of delayed rewards in substance abusers with gambling problems. Drug Alcohol Depend 56:25–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin H (2004) The science of self-control. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin H, Siegel E (1994) Temporal pattering in probabilistic choice. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 59:161–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin H, Raineri A, Cross D (1991) Subjective probability and delay. J Exp Anal Behav 55:233–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelt D, Train K (1998) Mixed logit with repeated choices: households’ choices of appliance efficiency level. Rev Econ Stat 80:647–657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelt D, Train K (2000) Specific taste parameters and mixed logit, Working paper no. E00-274. Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds B, Karraker K, Horn K, Richards JB (2003) Delay and probability discounting as related to different stages of adolescent smoking and non-smoking. Behav Process 64:333–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds B, Richards JB, Horn K, Karraker K (2004) Delay discounting and probability discounting as related to cigarette smoking status in adults. Behav Process 65:35–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rimm EB, Can J, Stampfer MJ, Colditz GA, Willett WC (1995) Prospective study of cigarette smoking, alcohol use, and the risk of diabetes in men. Br Med J 310:555–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose JE, Brauer LH, Behm FM, Cramblett M, Calkins K, Lawhon D (2004) Psychopharmacological interactions between nicotine and ethanol. Nicotine Tob Res 6:133–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1937) A note on measurement of utility. Rev Econ Stud 4:155–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sozou PD (1998) On hyperbolic discounting and uncertain hazard rates. Proc R Soc B Biol Sci 265:2015–2020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ, Becker GS (1977) De Gustibus Non Est Dispuandum. Am Econ Rev 67:76–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Takahashi T (2005) Loss of self-control in intertemporal choice may be attributable to logarithmic time-perception. Med Hypotheses 65:691–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train KE (2003) Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tsuge T, Kishimoto A, Takeuchi K (2005) A choice experiment approach to the valuation of mortality. J Risk Uncertain 31:73–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viney R, Lanscar E, Louviere J (2002) Discrete choice experiments to measure preference for health and health care: expert review. Pharmacoecon Outcomes Res 2:319–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1953) Theory of games and economic behaviour. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Warner JT, Pleeter S (2001) The personal discount rate: evidence from military downsizing programs. Am Econ Rev 91:33–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winston GC (1980) Addiction and backsliding: a theory of compulsive consumption. J Econ Behav Organ 1:295–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization (2013) WHO report on the global tobacco epidemic, 2013: enforcing bans on tobacco advertising, promotion and sponsorship. World Health Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Yi R, de la Piedad X, Bickel WK (2006) The combined effects of delay and probability in discounting. Behav Process 73:149–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi R, Chase WD, Bickel WK (2007) Probability discounting among cigarette smokers and nonsmokers: molecular analysis discerns group differences. Behav Pharmacol 18:633–639

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Takanori Ida .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Addendum: Recent Developments

This addendum has been newly written for this book chapter.

Addendum: Recent Developments

Smoking is still the most common cause of morbidity and mortality in Japan, with about 130,000 people estimated to die annually from smoking-related diseases (Ikeda et al. 2012). Decreased tobacco use has been shown to reduce the development of smoking-related diseases and death in smokers (Glantz and Gonzalez 2012). Therefore, anti-tobacco policies have been a global issue. In Japan, the enforcement of the Health Promotion Law (2002) promote various tobacco-controlling approaches such as restricting smoking in public places and raising the tax on tobacco. However, in Japan, these measures have proven inadequate compared with other industrialized nations (WHO 2013).

In order to explore factors drive smokers’ attempts to quit as well as the investigations about different features of preferences according to smoking history, Goto et al. (2007) have analyzed the willingness of smokers to quit their habit in given hypothetical conditions using discrete choice experiments (DCEs). See also Goto et al. (2011) for a developed research.

In the DCE, any goods or services are described by bundling their attributes or characteristics. The extent to which an individual values goods or services can be evaluated by the selection of hypothetical choices that mimic the daily decision-making process. This technique has often been applied in health-care settings. In this study, the following five attributes were identified as the most important factors: the price of a pack of cigarettes, fines for smoking in public places, long-term health risks (mortality risk), short-term health risks (risk of upper respiratory infection), and health risks to others.

Table 7.8 shows summary of results of the DCE which collects the data from 616 smokers, stratified with Fagerstrom test for nicotine dependence (FTND). The impacts of attributes other than the cigarette price differ remarkably among smokers with different levels of nicotine dependence. The price of cigarettes has the shortest term and certain effect on smokers relative to other variables such as health risks and penalties—that is, our DCE results indicated that the shortest term and certain effects are significant or all types of smokers, while the longer and risky term effects such as health risks are found only in smokers with lower nicotine dependence. These results imply the importance of time/risk preference parameters also from tobacco-controlling policy perspective.

Table 7.8 Impacts of attributes on smoking on quit attempts

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ida, T., Goto, R. (2016). Interdependency Among Addictive Behaviours and Time/Risk Preferences: Discrete Choice Model Analysis of Smoking, Drinking, and Gambling. In: Ikeda, S., Kato, H., Ohtake, F., Tsutsui, Y. (eds) Behavioral Economics of Preferences, Choices, and Happiness. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55402-8_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics