Skip to main content

Industrial Hollowing Under a Flexible Exchange Rate System

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Keynesian Economics and Price Theory

Part of the book series: Advances in Japanese Business and Economics ((AJBE,volume 7))

  • 1177 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter considers the welfare implications of foreign direct investment (FDI) under a flexible exchange rate system, from the viewpoint of a macroeconomic theory. With FDI there can be a conflict between individual firms and the national economy as a whole. Although lower wages may be an incentive for firms to take advantage of FDI, the resulting economic surge may harm the national economy. This comes about first because an increase in unemployment in the home country will reduce that economy’s welfare, and second, an appreciation in the real exchange rate, caused by the remittance of earnings from foreign countries, will reduce the value of profits in terms of domestic goods. This appreciation entirely cancels the benefit from the cost reductions that induce FDI in lower-wage countries, and only the downturn in employment remains. In this sense, a glut in FDI is harmful, and some coordination is required between firms and their government to reduce its effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We assume that the foreign economy does not initially produce the tradable goods. Even after firms of the home economy constructs factories in the foreign economy, the real exchange rate within that economy is kept at unity because any firm faces the same nominal reservation wage.

  2. 2.

    The equilibrium path of the nominal exchange rate, \({{E}_{t}}\), is determined by the fundamental equation s within the home and the foreign economy; that is, by the fundamental equation within the foreign economy, where the prices of tradable and non-tradable goods are equal, \(\alpha {{A}^{-1}}{{[1-{{\eta }^{-1}}]}^{-1}}{{[{{\rho }^{f}}]}^{1-c}}=1\). Here, \({{\rho }^{f}}\) is the inflation rate within the foreign economy. This equation is essentially the same as Eq. (9.18). The fundamental equation of the home economy is Eq. (9.20) Then \({{\left[\frac{{{\rho }^{f}}}{{{\rho }^{h}}}\right]}^{1-c}}\cdot {{e}^{\frac{1}{2}}}=1\). Since the relative prices between the tradable and non-tradable goods are kept constant over time, it is clear that \(\frac{{{\rho }^{f}}}{{{\rho }^{h}}}=\frac{{{E}_{t}}}{{{E}_{t+1}}}\) holds. Thus, the path of the nominal exchange rate is determined as \({{\left[\frac{{{E}_{t}}}{{{E}_{t+1}}}\right]}^{1-c}}\cdot {{e}^{\frac{1}{2}}}=1\).

  3. 3.

    Since the carried-over money of the older generation depends on the income of the previous period, there is an adjustment process towards stationary state. To clarify the discussion, we abbreviate the process.

  4. 4.

    The government of the home economy is assumed to keep the real cash balance constant over time. Then, the budget constraint of the government implies: \({{g}_{t}}=\frac{{{M}_{t}}-{{M}_{t-1}}}{p_{t}^{NT}}=m-\frac{{{M}_{t-1}}}{p_{t}^{NT}}\). Where: \({{g}_{t}}\) is the real government expenditure in terms of the non-tradable goods.

    Since the total real cash balance that the older generation carried over is \(\frac{{{M}_{t-1}}}{p_{t}^{NT}}\), the sum of the government and the older generation’s expenditure is: \({{g}_{t}}+\frac{{{M}_{t-1}}}{p_{t}^{NT}}=m\).

  5. 5.

    Equation (9.26) is transformed taking Eq. (9.25) into consideration:

    \({{y}^{h}}-c\cdot \left[{{y}^{h}}-\frac{{{E}_{t}}\cdot \widetilde{W_{t}^{R}}}{p_{t}^{NT}}\cdot {{y}^{T}}\right]=m\).

    This implies that whenever the foreign exchange market and the aggregated goods market are cleared, the home currency market is also in equilibrium.

  6. 6.

    Note that, as shown in Chap. 2, social welfare is an increasing function of real profits that are proportionate to real GNP.

References

  • Caves RE (1971) International corporations: the industrial economics of foreign investment. Economica 38:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves RE (1982) Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood N, Young S (1979) The economics of multinational enterprise. Longman, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp MC (1964) The pure theory of international trade. Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • MacDougal GDA (1960) The benefits and costs of private investment from abroad: a theoretical approach. Econ Rec 36:13–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otaki M (2012) A macroeconomic consequence of foreign direct investment: the welfare economics of industrial hollowing. Theor Econ Lett 2:412–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masayuki Otaki .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Otaki, M. (2015). Industrial Hollowing Under a Flexible Exchange Rate System. In: Keynesian Economics and Price Theory. Advances in Japanese Business and Economics, vol 7. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55345-8_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics