The Basic Model of Airline Network

Part of the New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives book series (NFRSASIPER, volume 13)


From the viewpoint of regional policy, the hub airport is crucial for developing the regional economy. Because various goods, services, and information are gathered in the hub city, many firms aggregate there. As these firms aggregate, many people are also drawn to the region and regional development ensues.


Potential Number Schedule Effect Schedule Delay Airline Network City Pair 


  1. 1.
    Alumur, S., & Kara, B. Y. (2008). Network hub location problems: The state of the art. European Journal of Operational Research, 190, 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. 2.
    Aykin, T. (1994). Lagrangian relaxation based approaches to capacitated hub-and-spoke network design problems. European Journal of Operational Research, 79, 501–523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. 3.
    Berechman, J., Poddar, S., & Shy, O. (1998). Network structure and entry in the deregulated airline industry. Keio Economic Studies, 35, 71–82.Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    Berechman, J., & Shy, O. (1996). The structure of airline equilibrium networks. In J. van den Bergh, P. Nijkamp, & P. Rietveld (Eds.), Recent advances in spatial equilibrium modeling: Methodology and applications (pp. 138–155). Berlin/New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. 5.
    Bittlingmayer, G. (1990). Efficiency and entry in a simple airline network. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 8, 245–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. 6.
    Brueckner, J. K. (2004). Network structure and airline scheduling. Journal of Industrial Economics, 52, 291–312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. 7.
    Brueckner, J. K., & Flores-Fillol, R. (2007). Airline schedule competition. Review of Industrial Organization, 30, 161–177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. 8.
    Brueckner, J. K., & Spiller, P. T. (1991). Competition and mergers in airline networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 323–342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. 9.
    Bryan, D. L., & O’Kelly, M. E. (1999). Hub-and-spoke networks in air transportation: An analytical review. Journal of Regional Science, 39, 275–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. 10.
    Campbell, J. F. (1994). Integer programming formulations of discrete hub location problems. European Journal of Operational Research, 72, 387–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. 11.
    De Camargo, R. S., Miranda, G., Jr., Ferreirab, R. P. M., & Lunac, H. P. (2008). Multiple allocation hub-and-spoke network design under hub congestion. Computers and Operations Research, 36, 3097–3106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. 12.
    Douglas, G. W., & Miller, J. C. (1974). Quality competition, industry equilibrium and efficiency in the price-constrained airline market. American Economic Review, 64, 657–669.Google Scholar
  13. 13.
    Eiselta, H. A., & Marianov, V. (2008). A conditional p-hub location problem with attraction functions. Computers and Operations Research, 36, 3128–3135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 14.
    Flores-Fillol, R. (2010). Congested hub. Transportation Research Part B, 44, 358–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. 15.
    Flores-Fillol, R., & Fageda, X. (2015). A note on optimal airline networks under airport congestion. Economics Letters, 128, 90–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. 16.
    Hendricks, K., Piccione, M., & Tan, G. (1995). The Economics of hubs: The case of monopoly. Review of Economics Studies, 62, 83–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. 17.
    Hendricks, K., Piccione, M., & Tan, G. (1997). Entry and exit in hub-spoke networks. Rand Journal of Economics, 28, 291–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. 18.
    Kawasaki, A. (2008). Network effects, heterogeneous time value, and network formation in the airline market. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 38, 388–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. 19.
    Kawasaki, A. (2012). Hub location with scheduling effects in a monopoly airline market. Annals of Regional Science, 49, 805–819.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. 20.
    Kawasaki, A., & Lin, M. H. (2013). Airline schedule competition and entry route choices of low-cost carriers. Australian Economic Review, 52, 97–114.Google Scholar
  21. 21.
    Konishi, H. (2000). Formation of hub cities: Transportation cost advantage and population agglomeration. Journal of Urban Economics, 48, 1–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. 22.
    Martin, J. C., & Roman, C. (2004). Analyzing competition for hub location in intercontinental aviation markets. Transportation Research Part E, 40, 135–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. 23.
    O’Kelly, M. E. (1987). A quadratic integer program for the location of interacting hub facilities. European Journal of Operational Research, 32, 393–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. 24.
    Oum, T. H., Zhang, A., & Zhang, Y. (1995). Airline network rivalry. Canadian Journal of Economics, 28, 836–857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. 25.
    Panzar, J. C. (1979). Equilibrium and welfare in unregulated airline markets. American Economic Review, 69, 92–95.Google Scholar
  26. 26.
    Pels, E., Nijkamp, P., & Rietveld, P. (1997). Substitution and complementarity in aviation: Airports vs. airlines. Transportation Research Part E, 33, 275–286.Google Scholar
  27. 27.
    Racunica, I., & Wynter, L. (2005). Optimal location of intermodal freight hubs. Transportation Research Part B, 39, 435–477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. 28.
    Rodriguez, V., Alvarez, M. J., & Barcos, L. (2007). Hub location under capacity constraints. Transportation Research Part E, 43, 495–505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. 29.
    Shy, O. (1995). Industrial organization: Theory and applications. Cambridge: MIT.Google Scholar
  30. 30.
    Teraji, Y., & Morimoto, Y. (2014). Price Competition of airports and its effect on the airline network. Economics of Transportation, 3, 45–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. 31.
    Tirole, J. (1998). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge: MIT.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Japan 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Faculty of EducationKagoshima UniversityKagoshima cityJapan

Personalised recommendations