Skip to main content

Spectral Decompositions of Single-Product Economies

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 790 Accesses

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science ((EESCS,volume 2))

Abstract

This chapter follows a recently developed line of research, which focuses on the spectral analysis of the wage-price-profit rate relationships in actual single-product economies. It shows that main aspects of those relationships could be connected to the skew distribution of both the eigenvalues and the singular values of the system matrices. The results finally suggest that there is room for using low-dimensional models as surrogates for actual economies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This chapter draws on Mariolis and Tsoulfidis (2011, 2014), Iliadi et al. (2014), Mariolis (2011, 2013, 2015) and Mariolis et al. (2015). In the present line of research, there have also been contributions by Schefold (2008, 2013) and Mariolis and Tsoulfidis (2009), while Bienenfeld (1988, p. 255) has already shown that, in the extreme case where the non-dominant eigenvalues of the matrix of vertically integrated technical coefficients equal zero, the production prices in terms of Sraffa’s Standard commodity (SSC) are strictly linear functions of the profit rate, and Shaikh (1998) has noted that ‘[a] large disparity between first and second eigenvalues is another possible source of linearity.’. (p. 244; also see p. 250, note 9).

  2. 2.

    Steedman’s (1999) numeraire entails that

    $$ {\left({\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{\Pi}_i}{d}_i\right)}^{-1}=1 $$

    and, therefore, w = ∏0 and

    $$ \mathbf{p}={\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{\Pi}_i{\mathbf{y}}_{\mathbf{J}i}} $$

    (see Eqs. 5.9a and 5.10a). Thus, the wρ and pρ relationships take on simpler forms in the sense that the former is expressed solely in terms of the eigenvalues of J, while the latter is expressed in terms of powers of ρ up to ρ n−1.

  3. 3.

    If, for instance, \( \mathbf{T}=\left[{\mathbf{x}}_{\mathbf{J}1}^{\mathrm{T}},{\mathbf{e}}_2^{\mathrm{T}},\dots, {\mathbf{e}}_n^{\mathrm{T}}\right] \), then \( {\tilde{\mathbf{J}}}_{12}={\left({\mathbf{y}}_{\mathbf{J}1}{\mathbf{x}}_{\mathbf{J}1}^{\mathrm{T}}\right)}^{-1}\left[{y}_{2\mathbf{J}1},{y}_{3\mathbf{J}1},\dots, {y}_{n\mathbf{J}1}\right] \).

  4. 4.

    Consider the theorem mentioned in footnote 31 of Chap. 2. It may be added that, if, for instance, x > 0 and \( {y}_{1i}={x}_{i1}^{-1}+{\delta}_i \), where δ i ≥ 0, then

    $$ \lambda \approx {\left(1+n+{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{x}_{i1}{\delta}_i}\right)}^{-1}\le {\left(1+n\right)}^{-1} $$

    If x > 0 and \( {y}_{1i}=-{x}_{i1}^{-1}+{\delta}_i \), where δ i ≤ 0, then

    $$ \lambda \approx {\left(1-n+{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{x}_{i1}{\delta}_i}\right)}^{-1}\ge {\left(1-n\right)}^{-1} $$
  5. 5.

    It is noted that if we adopt Steedman’s numeraire (see footnote 2 in this chapter) and \( {\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}k}=\lambda =\alpha \), then

    $$ \mathbf{p}={\left(1-\rho \lambda \right)}^{n-2}\left\{\mathbf{p}(0)+\rho \left[{\left(1-\lambda \right)}^{-n+2}\mathbf{p}(1)-\mathbf{p}(0)\right]\right\} $$

    where p(1) is now equal to (1–λ)n−1 y J1. Hence, the p j ρ curves are not necessarily monotonic.

  6. 6.

    Any complex number is an eigenvalue of a positive 3 × 3 ‘circulant matrix’ (Minc 1988, p. 167). To the best of our knowledge, however, the problem of determining necessary and sufficient conditions for a list of numbers to be the spectrum of a nonnegative matrix (‘nonnegative inverse eigenvalue problem ’) remains unsolved (for a recent contribution, see Laffey and Šmigoc 2006).

  7. 7.

    Setting \( b={\left(1+\mathbf{y}{\mathbf{x}}^{\mathrm{T}}\right)}^{-1},\mathbf{S}=\mathbf{I},{\boldsymbol{\upchi}}^{\mathrm{T}}={\left(\mathbf{y}{\mathbf{x}}^{\mathrm{T}}\right)}^{-1}{\mathbf{x}}^{\mathrm{T}} \) and replacing e by y, we obtain Case 3.

  8. 8.

    It is easily checked that

    $$ {\dot{f}}_{\mu}\left(\rho \right)=-\left(1-{\lambda_{\mathbf{J}}}_{\mu}\right){\left(1-\rho {\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}\mu}\right)}^{-2}<0 $$

    since \( \left|{\lambda_{\mathbf{J}}}_{\mu}\right|<1 \), and

    $$ {\ddot{f}}_{\mu}\left(\rho \right)=-2\left(1-{\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}\mu}\right){\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}\mu }{\left(1-\rho {\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}\mu}\right)}^{-3} $$
  9. 9.

    See Sraffa (1960, pp. 31, footnote 2, 48 and 53–54). For the non-Sraffian, real and/or complex, Standard commodities-systems, also see Goodwin (1976, 1977, 1984), Cozzi (1990), Pasinetti (1990), Punzo (1990), Aruka (1991), Steenge (1995) and Rodousakis (2012).

  10. 10.

    It is easily checked that

    $$ \dot{g}\left(\rho \right)={\left(1-\rho \right)}^{-2}\left(1-\alpha \right) $$

    and

    $$ \dot{h}\left(\rho \right)={\left[\left(1-\rho \right)\left(1-\rho \alpha \right)\right]}^{-2}\rho {\beta}^2\left[2-\rho \left(1+\alpha \right)\right] $$

    Hence, \( \dot{g}\left(\rho \right)>0 \) and \( \dot{h}\left(\rho \right)>0 \), since \( \left|\alpha \right|<1 \) and ρ(1 + α) < 2.

  11. 11.

    It is easily checked that the first derivative of \( {\left({\left|{\kappa}_{\mu}\right|}^{-1}{\kappa}_{\mathrm{S}}\right)}^2 \) with respect to ρ equals

    $$ 2\left[\left(1-\rho \alpha \right)\left(1-\alpha \right)+\rho {\beta}^2\right]{\left[{\left(1-\rho \right)}^3\sqrt{\alpha^2+{\beta}^2}\right]}^{-1} $$
  12. 12.

    It may be said that this is not unanticipated on the basis of Goodwin’s (1976, 1977) contribution to the linear value and distribution theory. By following an approach which is closer to our, Bidard and Ehrbar (2007, pp. 203–204) show that |κ μ | decrease with ρ, and if κ μ is complex, then the derivative of its argument does not change sign, i.e. κ μ moves monotonically, either clockwise or counterclockwise, across the complex plane . Since there are statements in the foreign trade theory (e.g. Stolper-Samuelson effect, ‘factor price’ equalization theorem) that depend crucially on the existence of monotonic price-profit rate relationship s, our conclusion would seem to be of some importance for that theory (also see Mariolis 2004).

  13. 13.

    See, e.g. Horn and Johnson (1991, Chap. 3). Also recall that J is similar to the column stochastic matrix M (\( \equiv {\widehat{\mathbf{y}}}_{\mathbf{J}1}\mathbf{J}{\widehat{\mathbf{y}}}_{\mathbf{J}1}^{-1} \)).

  14. 14.

    See footnote 3 in this chapter.

  15. 15.

    It is noted that, in this example, M is ‘circulant ’ (since A is cyclic ) and, therefore, ‘normal ’ (MM T = M T M) and doubly stochastic : \( {\sigma}_{\mathbf{M}1}=\left|{\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}1}\right|=1 \), \( {\sigma}_{\mathbf{M}2}={\sigma}_{\mathbf{M}3}=\left|{\lambda}_{\mathbf{J}2,3}\right| \) and \( {\varepsilon}_{\mathbf{M}1}\cong 0.193 \), \( {\varepsilon}_{\mathbf{M}2}\cong 0.097 \) (see, e.g. Meyer 2001, pp. 379 and 555).

  16. 16.

    The dimensions of those SIOTs vary from 19 industries (Greece, 1988–1997) to 39 industries (USA). The tables of China and Japan are available from the OECD STAN database. Those of Greece and Korea are provided by the National Statistical Service of Greece and the Bank of Korea, respectively (also see Chap. 3). Finally, those of USA are from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and have been compiled by Juillard (1986) (the data used in the studies by Ochoa 1984; Bienenfeld 1988 and Shaikh 1998 are from the same source although at 71 × 71 industry detail).

  17. 17.

    Finkelstein and Friedberg (1967) discuss E and EN and apply them to studies of industrial competition and concentration, while Jasso (1982) and Bailey (1985) discuss SF and RE, respectively, and apply them to studies of income distribution . It may also be noted that there is a connection between SF and entropy : using π k , the former can be expressed as

    $$ SF=\left(n-1\right){\displaystyle \prod_{k=2}^n{\pi_k}^{{\left(n-1\right)}^{-1}}} $$

    or, taking the logarithm of both sides,

    $$ \log SF={E}_{\max }-\left[-{\left(n-1\right)}^{-1}{\displaystyle \sum_{k=2}^n \log }{\pi}_k\right] $$

    where log SF is known as the Wiener entropy and the term in brackets can be conceived as a ‘cross-entropy’ expression.

  18. 18.

    In fact, we tried an optimization procedure to find the best possible form, and from the many possibilities, we opted for a simple but, at the same time, general enough to fit the moduli of the eigenvalues of all countries and years.

  19. 19.

    It should be noted that we have also experimented with the flow SIOTs of Canada (1997, 34 × 34; source: OECD STAN database), Japan (1995–1997, 41 × 41; source: OECD STAN database), UK (1998, 40 × 40; source: OECD STAN database) and USA (1997, 40 × 40; source: BEA, compilation through the OECD STAN database), and the results were quite similar, i.e. SF, 0.359 (USA)–0.500 (UK); π 2, 8 % (UK)–18 % (Canada); RE, 0.811 (Canada)–0.888 (UK); and REN, 52 % (Canada)–67 % (UK).

  20. 20.

    The original input-output data comprised 108 industries and are published by the Statistical Service of Japan. The problem with this data set is that eight of the industries have zero rows (i.e. they do not deliver any output to the other sectors and to themselves), which give rise to an input-output structure with non-basic sectors and, therefore, zero eigenvalues corresponding to each of these eight industries. To sidestep this problem, we aggregated each of these eight industries to corresponding similar industries so as the resulting input-output structure consists of dimensions 100 × 100 basic industries. Finally, it should be noted that the results displayed in Table 5.2 are not comparable with those displayed in Table 5.1, since the 33 industries SIOTs of Japan are constructed using different sources and also methodology.

  21. 21.

    See Sect. 3.9. For completeness reasons, here, as well as in Sect. 5.3.2.1, we do not remove the elements associated with the industry ‘private households with employed persons’.

  22. 22.

    It may be recalled that

    $$ rank\left[{\mathbf{A}}^{\mathrm{C}}\right]+ rank\left[\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{A}\right]-n\le rank\left[{\mathbf{A}}^{\mathrm{C}}{\left[\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{A}\right]}^{-1}\right]\le \min \left\{ rank\left[{\mathbf{A}}^{\mathrm{C}}\right],\ rank\left[\mathbf{I}-\mathbf{A}\right]\right\} $$

    (see, e.g. Meyer 2001, p. 211). We also experimented with an aggregation in a 3 × 3 SIOT for the USA (1977): in the flow version, the modulus of the subdominant (complex) eigenvalue equals 0.146; in the stock version, the subdominant eigenvalue equals 0.031, while the third eigenvalue equals –0.0001. The aggregation in a 3 × 3 SIOT for Greece (1970) did not give any different results: in the flow version, the modulus of the subdominant (complex) eigenvalue equals 0.087; in the stock version, the subdominant eigenvalue equals –0.027, while the third eigenvalue equals zero (see Tsoulfidis 2010, pp. 150–155). Also consider the evidence provided by Steenge and Thissen (2005).

  23. 23.

    The same holds true for the German economy, while the functions associated with all the other economies of this sample are strictly decreasing.

  24. 24.

    It is noted that (i) p is identified with e; (ii) for the construction of [A,l] and the estimation of w, we follow the usual procedure; and (iii) the sectoral ‘profit factor s’ are estimated from

    $$ 1+{\overline{r}}_j=\left(1-w{l}_j\right){\left({a}_{1j}+\dots +{a}_{nj}\right)}^{-1} $$
  25. 25.

    For instance, the ‘root-mean-square-percent-error ’ or the distances à la Steedman-Tomkins (consider Chap. 4) lead to more complicated expressions. Thus, it is much more convenient to focus on the MAED.

  26. 26.

    Τhe effects of technical changes on the eigenvalues of A (and, therefore, on λ J k ) are unknown a priori. It could be noted that the first partial derivatives of λ A j with respect to the elements of A are given by

    $$ \partial {\lambda}_{\mathbf{A}j}/\partial \mathbf{A} \equiv \left[\partial {\lambda}_{\mathbf{A}j}/\partial {a}_{ij}\right]={\left({\mathbf{y}}_{\mathbf{A}j}{\mathbf{x}}_{\mathbf{A}j}^{\mathrm{T}}\right)}^{-1}\left({\mathbf{y}}_{\mathbf{A}j}^{\mathrm{T}}{\mathbf{x}}_{\mathbf{A}j}\right) $$

    (see, e.g. Phillips 1982 and Ipsen 1998).

  27. 27.

    We postulate that \( \mathbf{H} \equiv {\mathbf{A}}^{\mathrm{C}}{\left[\mathbf{I}-\left(\mathbf{A}+{\mathbf{A}}^{\mathrm{D}}\right)\right]}^{-1} \) (see Eq. 2.16a). It is also noted that the flow SIOT for the year 1970 (see Table 5.1) gives results similar to those reported in Tables 5.15 and 5.16.

References

  • Aruka, Y. (1991). Generalized Goodwin’s theorems on general coordinates. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 2(1), 69–91. Reprinted in Y. Aruka (Ed.) (2011), Complexities of production and interacting human behaviour (pp. 39–66). Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, K. D. (1985). Entropy measures of inequality. Sociological Inquiry, 55(2), 200–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bidard, C., & Ehrbar, H. G. (2007). Relative prices in the classical theory: Facts and figures. Bulletin of Political Economy, 1(2), 161–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bienenfeld, M. (1988). Regularity in price changes as an effect of changes in distribution. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12(2), 247–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bródy, A. (1997). The second eigenvalue of the Leontief matrix. Economic Systems Research, 9(3), 253–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cozzi, T. (1990). A comparison between Goodwin’s normalized general coordinates and Pasinetti’s vertical integration methods. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinear and multisectoral macrodynamics (pp. 165–172). New York: New York University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ding, J., & Zhou, A. (2007). Eigenvalues of rank-one updated matrices with some applications. Applied Mathematics Letters, 20(12), 1223–1226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ding, J., & Zhou, A. (2008). Characteristic polynomials of some perturbed matrices. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 199(2), 631–636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, Μ. Ο., & Friedberg, R. M. (1967). The application of an entropy theory of concentration to the Clayton act. The Yale Law Journal, 76(4), 677–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (2010). Topics in classical micro- and macroeconomics. Elements of a critique of neoricardian theory. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1976). Use of normalized general co-ordinates in linear value and distribution theory. In K. R. Polenske & J. V. Skolka (Eds.), Advances in input-output analysis (pp. 581–602). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1977). Capital theory in orthogonalised general co-ordinates. In R. M. Goodwin (Eds.), (1983), Essays in linear economic structures (pp. 153–172). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1984). Disaggregating models of fluctuating growth. In R. M. Goodwin, M. Krüger, & A. Vercelli (Eds.), Nonlinear models of fluctuating growth (pp. 67–72). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hartfiel, D. J., & Meyer, C. D. (1998). On the structure of stochastic matrices with a subdominant eigenvalue near 1. Linear Algebra and its Applications, 272(1–3), 193–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haveliwala, T. H., & Kamvar, S. D. (2003). The second eigenvalue of the Google matrix (Technical Report 2003-20). Stanford: Computer Science Department, Stanford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, R. A., & Johnson, C. R. (1991). Topics in matrix analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Iliadi, F., Mariolis, T., Soklis, G., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2014). Bienenfeld’s approximation of production prices and eigenvalue distribution: Further evidence from five European economies. Contributions to Political Economy, 33(1), 35–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ipsen, I. C. F. (1998). Relative perturbation results for matrix eigenvalues and singular values. Acta Numerica, 7, 151–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jasso, G. (1982). Measuring inequality: Using the geometric mean/arithmetic mean ratio. Sociological Methods and Research, 10(3), 303–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Juillard, M. (1986). Τhe input-output database for a departmental study of the US economy. New York: New School for Social Research. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffey, T. J., & Šmigoc, E. (2006). Nonnegative realization of spectra having negative real parts. Linear Algebra and its Applications, 416(1), 148–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1978). The interest rate equalisation theorem with non-traded goods. Journal of International Economics, 8(1), 11–19. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.) (1979), Fundamental Issues in Trade Theory (pp. 90–98). London: Macmillan.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L., & Steedman, I. (2000). On the probability of re-switching and capital reversing in a two-sector Sraffian model. In H. D. Kurz (Ed.), Critical essays on Piero Sraffa’s legacy in economics (pp. 323–354). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2004). A Sraffian approach to the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. Asian-African Journal of Economics and Econometrics, 4(1), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2011). A simple measure of price-labour value deviation. Metroeconomica, 62(4), 605–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2013). Applying the mean absolute eigen-deviation of labour commanded prices from labour values to actual economies. Applied Mathematical Sciences, 7(104), 5193–5204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2015). Norm bounds and a homographic approximation for the wage-profit curve. Metroeconomica, 66(2), 263–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2009). Decomposing the changes in production prices into ‘capital-intensity’ and ‘price’ effects: Theory and evidence from the Chinese economy. Contributions to Political Economy, 28(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2011). Eigenvalue distribution and the production price-profit rate relationship: Theory and empirical evidence. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 8(1), 87–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2014). On Bródy’s conjecture: Theory, facts and figures about instability of the US economy. Economic Systems Research, 26(2), 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., Rodousakis, N., & Christodoulaki, A. (2015). Input-output evidence on the relative price effects of total productivity shift. International Review of Applied Economics, 29(2), 150–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, C. D. (2001). Matrix analysis and applied linear algebra. New York: Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minc, H. (1988). Nonnegative matrices. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ochoa, E. (1984). Labor values and prices of production: An interindustry study of the U.S. economy, 1947–1972 (Ph.D. Dissertation, New School for Social Research, New York, USA).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. L. (1990). Normalised general coordinates and vertically integrated sectors in a simple case. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinear and multisectoral macrodynamics (pp. 151–164). New York: New York University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, P. C. B. (1982). A simple proof of the latent root sensitivity formula. Economics Letters, 9(1), 57–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Punzo, L. F. (1990). Generalised diagonal coordinates in dynamical analysis, and capital and distribution theory. In K. Velupillai (Ed.), Nonlinear and multisectoral macrodynamics (pp. 173–197). New York: New York University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rodousakis, N. (2012). Goodwin’s Lotka-Volterra model in disaggregative form: A correction note. Metroeconomica, 63(4), 599–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (2008). Families of strongly curved and of nearly linear wage curves: A contribution to the debate about the surrogate production function. Bulletin of Political Economy, 2(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (2013). Approximate surrogate production functions. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(5), 1161–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. M. (1998). The empirical strength of the labour theory of value. In R. Bellofiore (Ed.), Marxian economics: A reappraisal (Vol. 2, pp. 225–251). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities. Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1999). Values do follow a simple rule! Economic Systems Research, 11(1), 5–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steenge, A. E. (1995). Sraffa and Goodwin: A unifying framework for standards of value in the income distribution problem. Journal of Economics, 62(1), 55–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steenge, A. E., & Thissen, M. J. P. M. (2005). A new matrix theorem: Interpretation in terms of internal trade structure and implications for dynamic systems. Journal of Economics, 84(1), 71–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treitel, S., & Shanks, J. L. (1971). The design of multistage separable planar filters. Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers Transactions on Geoscience Electronics, 9(1), 10–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2010). Competing schools of economic thought. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mariolis, T., Tsoulfidis, L. (2016). Spectral Decompositions of Single-Product Economies. In: Modern Classical Economics and Reality. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 2. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55004-4_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics