Skip to main content

Measures of Production Price-Labour Value Deviation and Production Conditions

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Modern Classical Economics and Reality

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science ((EESCS,volume 2))

  • 785 Accesses

Abstract

Empirical studies indicate that the deviations of actual production prices from labour values are not too sensitive to the type of measure used for their evaluation. This chapter attempts to theorize this fact by focusing on the relationships between the ‘traditional’ and the numeraire-free measures of deviation. It also provides an illustration of these relationships using actual input-output data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Ochoa (1984, Chaps. 6–8; 1989, pp. 418–422), Petrović (1987, pp. 206–208), Chilcote (1997, Chaps. 6–7), Shaikh (1998, p. 233), Tsoulfidis and Maniatis (2002, pp. 365), Tsoulfidis and Rieu (2006, p. 289), Tsoulfidis and Mariolis (2007, p. 428), Tsoulfidis (2008, p. 715), Tsoulfidis and Paitaridis (2009, p. 221), Sánchez and Ferràndez (2010, p. 90), Mariolis and Soklis (2011, pp. 616–617), Sánchez and Montibeler (2015, pp. 336–339) and Chap. 3 in this book. What follows draws heavily on Mariolis and Tsoulfidis (2010, 2014) and Mariolis and Soklis (2011).

  2. 2.

    Throughout the chapter, we use the term ‘error ’ because we hypothesize that the d – distance represents the ‘true or accepted’ value of the deviation under study. However, see the Appendix at the end of this chapter.

  3. 3.

    For an alternative measure, i.e. the ‘mean absolute eigen-deviation of labour-commanded prices from labour values’, see Sect. 5.3.4.

  4. 4.

    Iff the vector of direct labour coefficients is the left P-F eigenvector of the matrix of direct technical coefficients, then f = v for each r (see Sect. 2.2.1.1).

  5. 5.

    Throughout the chapter, ‘most reliable’ means that the relative error is less than 3 %. It may also be noted that \( {\Delta}_{\mathrm{I}}\left(\delta \right)={\Delta}_{\mathrm{I}}\left({\delta}^{-1}\right) \). Moreover, when f decreases with r, (i) Eq. 4.7 holds with (1− δ) and, therefore, (ii) \( {d}_{\mathrm{I}}\left(+\infty \right)-{d}_{\mathrm{I}}(0) \) equals \( 2{d}_{\mathrm{I}}(0){d}_{\mathrm{I}}\left(+\infty \right) \).

  6. 6.

    The relative error associated with \( {d}_{\mathrm{I}}\left(+\infty \right) \) and (d II)min tends to \( 1-{\left(2\sqrt{2-\sqrt{2}}\right)}^{-1}\cong 34.7\% \) and \( 1-{\left(\sqrt{4-2\sqrt{2}}\right)}^{-1}\cong 7.6\% \), respectively.

  7. 7.

    It should be noted that to any given \( {z}_n^{-1}{\mathbf{z}}^{\mathrm{T}} \) there corresponds a unique b, while the converse does not hold true.

  8. 8.

    Given that the entire price vector cannot be proportional to that of labour values at a positive level of the profit rate (see Sect. 2.2.1.1), the case \( {\delta}_k=1,\kern0.5em k=1,2,\dots, n-1 \), does not really exist.

  9. 9.

    Consequently, \( \cos \theta \cong 0.9906 \), \( {\theta}^{\circ}\cong 7.8 \), \( d\cong 0.137 \), \( {d}_{\mathrm{II}}\left({{\mathbf{z}}^{\mathrm{T}}}^{*}\right)\cong 0.138 \), \( {\left({d}_{\mathrm{II}}\right)}_{\min}\cong 0.136 \), \( 43/52\le \mu \left({\mathbf{z}}^{\mathrm{T}}\right)\le 43/36 \) and \( \mu \left({{\mathbf{z}}^{\mathrm{T}}}^{*}\right)={ \cos}^2\theta \cong 0.981>43/44 \).

  10. 10.

    In the Greek economy (1988–1997), the actual value of ρ lies between 0.230 (1993) and 0.270 (1997), and in the Japanese economy (1970, 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990), it lies between 0.298 (1975) and 0.371 (1985) (see Sect. 3.3).

  11. 11.

    That is, \( \mathbf{p}{\overline{\mathbf{s}}}^{\mathrm{T}}=\overline{\mathbf{v}}{\overline{\mathbf{s}}}^{\mathrm{T}}=\overline{\mathbf{v}}{\overline{\mathbf{x}}}^{\mathrm{T}}=\mathbf{e}{\overline{\mathbf{x}}}^{\mathrm{T}} \) (see Sect. 3.3).

  12. 12.

    The Euclidean distance between two normalized vectors is known as the ‘Radner-McKenzie distance ’. In this definition, the Euclidean norm of a vector χ can be replaced by other norms such as \( {\displaystyle \sum_{j=1}^n\left|{\chi}_j\right|} \) (Inada 1964).

  13. 13.

    In accordance with most of the empirical studies on this topic, Steedman and Tomkins (1998) pay regard to measure ‘the extent to which (with-profit) prices diverge from (zero-profit) values’ (p. 379).

  14. 14.

    It need hardly be said that, in terms (at least) of the Leontief-Bródy approach (see Eq. 2.16a), this construction remains valid for the (more realistic) case of fixed capital and/or differential profit rates (also see Steedman and Tomkins 1998, pp. 381–382).

References

  • Chilcote, E. B. (1997). Interindustry structure, relative prices, and productivity: An input-output study of the U.S. and O.E.C.D. countries (Ph.D. Dissertation, New School for Social Research, New York).

    Google Scholar 

  • Inada, K.-I. (1964). Some structural characteristics of turnpike theorems. The Review of Economic Studies, 31(1), 43–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Soklis, G. (2011). On constructing numeraire-free measures of price-value deviation: A note on the Steedman-Tomkins distance. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35(3), 613–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2009). Decomposing the changes in production prices into ‘capital-intensity’ and ‘price’ effects: Theory and evidence from the Chinese economy. Contributions to Political Economy, 28(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2010). Measures of production price-labour value deviation and income distribution in actual economies: A note. Metroeconomica, 61(4), 701–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2014). Measures of production price-labour value deviation and income distribution in actual economies: Theory and empirical evidence. Bulletin of Political Economy, 8(1), 77–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ochoa, E. (1984). Labor values and prices of production: An interindustry study of the U.S. economy, 1947–1972 (Ph.D. Dissertation, New School for Social Research, New York).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ochoa, E. (1989). Value, prices and wage-profit curves in the U.S. economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 13(3), 413–429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrović, P. (1987). The deviation of production prices from labour values: Some methodological and empirical evidence. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 11(3), 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez, C., & Ferràndez, M. N. (2010). Valores, precios de producción y precios de mercado a partir de los datos de la economía española. Investigacion Economica, 69(274), 87–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez, C., & Montibeler, E. E. (2015). The labour theory of value and the prices in China (in Spanish). Economia e Sociedade, 24(2), 329–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. M. (1998). The empirical strength of the labour theory of value. In R. Bellofiore (Ed.), Marxian economics: A reappraisal (Vol. 2, pp. 225–251). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities. Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1977). Marx after Sraffa. London: New Left Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I., & Tomkins, J. (1998). On measuring the deviation of prices from values. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 22(3), 379–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2008). Price-value deviations: Further evidence from input-output data of Japan. International Review of Applied Economics, 22(6), 707–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Maniatis, T. (2002). Values, prices of production and market prices: Some more evidence from the Greek economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26(3), 359–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Mariolis, T. (2007). Labour values, prices of production and the effects of income distribution: Evidence from the Greek economy. Economic Systems Research, 19(4), 425–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Paitaridis, D. (2009). On the labor theory of value: Statistical artefacts or regularities? Research in Political Economy, 25, 209–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., & Rieu, D.-M. (2006). Labor values, prices of production, and wage-profit rate frontiers of the Korean economy. Seoul Journal of Economics, 19(3), 275–295.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Numeraire -Free Measures

Appendix: Numeraire -Free Measures

Consider the price-wage-profit system described by

$$ \mathbf{p}=w\mathbf{l}+\left(1+r\right)\mathbf{p}\mathbf{A} $$

or

$$ \mathbf{p}=w\mathbf{v}+\rho \mathbf{p}\mathbf{J} $$
(4.23)

(see Eqs. 2.1 and 2.16). For ρ = 0, we get \( \mathbf{p}(0)=w\mathbf{v} \), while for ρ = 1, we get \( \mathbf{p}(1)=\mathbf{p}(1)\mathbf{J} \), i.e. p(1) is a left P-F eigenvector of J. Postmultiplying Eq. 4.23 by \( {\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right)\right]}^{-1} \), where \( \mathbf{p}\left(\overline{\rho}\right) \) denotes the price vector associated with an arbitrarily chosen level, \( \overline{\rho} \), of the relative profit rate, gives

$$ {\mathbf{p}}^{*}=w{\mathbf{v}}^{*}+\rho {\mathbf{p}}^{*}{\mathbf{J}}^{*} $$
(4.24)

where \( {\mathbf{J}}^{*}\equiv \widehat{\mathbf{p}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right)\mathbf{J}{\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right)\right]}^{-1} \) denotes the transformed (via a diagonal similarity matrix formed from the elements of \( \mathbf{p}\left(\overline{\rho}\right) \)) matrix of the system, the elements of which are independent of the normalization of p, and \( {\mathbf{p}}^{*}\equiv \mathbf{p}{\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right)\right]}^{-1},{\mathbf{v}}^{*}\equiv \mathbf{v}{\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right)\right]}^{-1} \) the transformed vectors of prices and labour values, respectively.

Now suppose that one changes the units in which the various commodity quantities are measured. The shift of units converts [Al] to \( \left[\tilde{\mathbf{A}},\ \tilde{\mathbf{l}}\right] \), where \( \tilde{\mathbf{A}}\equiv \mathbf{D}\mathbf{A}{\mathbf{D}}^{-1} \), \( \tilde{\mathbf{l}}\equiv \mathbf{l}{\mathbf{D}}^{-1} \) and D is a diagonal matrix with positive diagonal elements. However, no element in Eq. 4.24 changes, since the original (non-transformed) vectors of labour values and prices change to \( \mathbf{v}{\mathbf{D}}^{-1} \) and \( \mathbf{p}{\mathbf{D}}^{-1} \), respectively. Thus, the angle, θ, between p * and v *, which is determined by

$$ \cos \theta ={\left({\left\Vert {\mathbf{p}}^{*}\right\Vert}_2{\left\Vert {\mathbf{v}}^{*}\right\Vert}_2\right)}^{-1}\left({\mathbf{p}}^{*}{\mathbf{v}}^{*}\right) $$

is independent of the choice of physical measurement units. Let \( d\left(\overline{\rho},\rho \right) \) be the Euclidean distance between the unit vector s \( {\mathbf{p}}^{**}\equiv {\left({\left\Vert {\mathbf{p}}^{*}\right\Vert}_2\right)}^{-1}{\mathbf{p}}^{*} \) and \( {\mathbf{v}}^{**}\equiv {\left({\left\Vert {\mathbf{v}}^{*}\right\Vert}_2\right)}^{-1}{\mathbf{v}}^{*} \) as a function of ρ.Footnote 12 Then

$$ d\left(\overline{\rho},\rho \right)\equiv {\left\Vert {\mathbf{p}}^{**}-{\mathbf{v}}^{**}\right\Vert}_2=\sqrt{2\left(1- \cos \theta \right)} $$

constitutes a measure of price-value or, equivalently, value-price deviation, which is independent of any choice of numeraire and physical measurement units. If \( \overline{\rho}=0 \), then \( {\mathbf{p}}^{*}=\mathbf{p}{\left[w\widehat{\mathbf{v}}\right]}^{-1} \), \( {\mathbf{v}}^{*}={w}^{-1}\mathbf{e} \) and

$$ d\left(0,\rho \right)={d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left(\rho \right)\equiv {\left\Vert {\left({\left\Vert \mathbf{p}{\widehat{\mathbf{v}}}^{-1}\right\Vert}_2\right)}^{-1}\left(\mathbf{p}{\widehat{\mathbf{v}}}^{-1}\right)-{\left(\sqrt{n}\right)}^{-1}\mathbf{e}\right\Vert}_2 $$

i.e. d(0, ρ) equals the d – distance , proposed by Steedman and Tomkins (1998, p. 382), and measures the deviation of the original prices from the original labour values, and not vice versa, in the sense that, in general,

$$ {d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left(\rho \right)\ne {d}_{\mathbf{v}}\left(\rho \right)\equiv {\left\Vert {\left({\left\Vert \mathbf{v}{\widehat{\mathbf{p}}}^{-1}\right\Vert}_2\right)}^{-1}\left(\mathbf{v}{\widehat{\mathbf{p}}}^{-1}\right)-{\left(\sqrt{n}\right)}^{-1}\mathbf{e}\right\Vert}_2 $$

(except for the case where n = 2).Footnote 13 If \( \overline{\rho}=1 \), then \( {\mathbf{p}}^{*}=\mathbf{p}{\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}(1)\right]}^{-1} \), \( {\mathbf{v}}^{*}=\mathbf{v}{\left[\widehat{\mathbf{p}}(1)\right]}^{-1} \) and, in general, \( d\left(1,\rho \right)\ne {d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left(\rho \right) \). Finally, at \( \rho =\overline{\rho} \) we obtain \( {\mathbf{p}}^{*}=\mathbf{e} \) and, therefore, \( d\left(\overline{\rho},\overline{\rho}\right)={d}_{\mathbf{v}}\left(\overline{\rho}\right) \) measures the deviation of the original labour values from the original prices corresponding to \( \overline{\rho} \) (and not vice versa).Footnote 14

The empirical results provided by Mariolis and Soklis (2011, pp. 616–617) are associated with input-output data from the Swedish economy for the year 2005 (n = 50), where the actual value of ρ is approximately equal to 0.520 or, if wages are paid ex ante, 0.368 (\( R\cong 0.807 \)), and the distances (i) \( d\left(0,\rho \right)={d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left(\rho \right) \), (ii) d(1, ρ), (iii) \( d\left(\overline{\rho},\rho \right),\ \overline{\rho}=0.8 \) (for instance) and (iv) d v (ρ). Those results suggest that:

  1. (i)

    The distances increase with \( \rho, 0\le \rho \le 1 \). Nevertheless, they tend to be close to each other for ‘low’ values of ρ. For instance, at the actual value of the relative profit rate, ρ a, they are in the range of 0.184–0.216, i.e.

    $$ {d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left({\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.184<{d}_{\mathbf{v}}\left({\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.202<d\left(0.8,{\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.215<d\left(1,{\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.216 $$

    or, if wages are paid ex ante, in the range of 0.127–0.144, i.e.

    $$ {d}_{\mathbf{p}}\left({\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.127<{d}_{\mathbf{v}}\left({\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.134<d\left(1,{\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.141<d\left(0.8,{\rho}^{\mathrm{a}}\right)\cong 0.144 $$
  2. (ii)

    As expected, the curve d v (ρ) intersects the curves d(1, ρ) and d(0.8, ρ) at ρ = 1 and ρ = 0.8, respectively. The curve d(1, ρ) also intersects the curves d(0.8, ρ), d v (ρ) and d p (ρ) at \( \rho \cong 0.470 \), \( \rho \cong 0.075 \) and \( \rho \cong 0.057 \), respectively.

It emerges, therefore, that the ranking of these numeraire -free measures is a priori unknown (even when the measures are monotonic functions of the relative profit rate).

It has been shown that in order to construct a measure of price-value deviation, which does not depend on the choice of numeraire and physical measurement units, it suffices to transform the price-wage-profit system via a diagonal similarity matrix formed from the elements of the price vector corresponding to a value of the relative profit rate. This implies that there exists an infinite number of such measures, whose ranking is a priori unknown, and the choice between them depends either on the theoretical viewpoint or the aim of the observer. Schematically speaking, we could say that observers thinking in Marxian terms would prefer to use d p (ρ), i.e. the d – distance , while those thinking in ‘Marx after Sraffa’ terms would prefer to use d v (ρ), since the determination of prices is ‘logically prior to any determination of value magnitudes’ (Steedman 1977, p. 65), or, more generally, \( d\left(\overline{\rho},\rho \right) \), with \( \overline{\rho}>0 \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mariolis, T., Tsoulfidis, L. (2016). Measures of Production Price-Labour Value Deviation and Production Conditions. In: Modern Classical Economics and Reality. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 2. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55004-4_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics