Skip to main content

Old and Modern Classical Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science ((EESCS,volume 2))

Abstract

This introductory chapter outlines the central relationships amongst classical, traditional neoclassical and modern classical theories of value, distribution and capital. It then argues that the state variable representation of linear systems could be conceived of as an approach for revealing the essential properties of a linear system of production of commodities and positive profits by means of commodities and, therefore, determining the extent to which these properties deviate from those predicted by the traditional capital theories.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a history-of-economic thought discussion of the structures of the classical and the neoclassical approaches, see Tsoulfidis (2010, Chaps. 6 and 7, 2011).

  2. 2.

    Also consider Pasinetti (1959–1960, 1981), Eatwell (1983), Garegnani (1984) and Steedman (1979a, Chaps. 1–3, 1998).

  3. 3.

    As Kurz (2014, p. 11) remarks, ‘the same kind of criticism can be found also in most recent times’ (and refers, as an example, two papers by Kenneth J. Arrow, published in 1972 and 1991).

  4. 4.

    For criticisms of this statement, and way of closing the system, see, e.g. Samuelson (1975, p. 493) and Fan (1983).

  5. 5.

    See Bhaduri (1966), Pasinetti (1966), Garegnani (1970), Steedman (1979a, b), Kurz and Salvadori (1995) and the references therein. In modern classical economics system, the real wage rate(s) is not necessarily an exogenously given variable. That system determines relations between, on the one hand, distributive variables and commodity prices and, on the other hand, growth , physical outputs and labour allocations. Thus, there are alternative ways of closing it (consider, for instance, the ‘monetary theory of distribution ’, i.e. the possible determination of the profit rate by the money interest rate ; Sraffa 1960, p. 33, Panico 1988, Pivetti 1991).

  6. 6.

    Matrices (and vectors) are delineated in boldface letters. The transpose of a 1×n vector ψ ≡ [ψ j] is denoted by ψ T. The diagonal matrix formed from the elements of ψ will be denoted by \( \widehat{\boldsymbol{\uppsi}} \), and I will denote the n×n identity matrix.

  7. 7.

    By definition, this axiomatization is incomplete for systems that include agents’ expectations about the future. In that case, ‘the future influences the present just as much as the past’ (Friedrich Nietzsche) and, therefore, the concept of futurität (futurity ) becomes indispensable (see, e.g. Willke 1993, Chap. 4).

  8. 8.

    If there is not a complete set of eigenvectors, matrix A cannot be reduced to a diagonal form by a similarity transformation and, therefore, the original system cannot be decomposed into a set of uncoupled first-order sub-systems (we will return to this issue in Chap. 2). It is always possible, however, to find a basis in which A is almost diagonal (‘Jordan normal form ’; see, e.g. Meyer 2001, Sects. 7.8 and 7.9). In that case, the transformed system (also) contains ‘chains’ of first-order sub-systems (associated with a particular system eigenvalue), where the output of one is the input of another.

  9. 9.

    In that case, the eigenvalues of [AI] all have negative real part (and vice versa); thus, the equilibrium point of system (1.1a), with γ(t)=γ, is asymptotically stable.

References

  • Bhaduri, A. (1966). The concept of the marginal productivity of capital and the Wicksell effect. Oxford Economic Papers, 18(3), 284–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burmeister, E. (1975). A comment on “This age of Leontief … and who?”. Journal of Economic Literature, 13(2), 454–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dmitriev, V. K. (1898). The theory of value of David Ricardo: An attempt at a rigorous analysis. In V. K. Dmitriev (Ed.) ([1904] 1974), Economic essays on value, competition and utility (pp. 37–95). Edited with an introduction by D. M. Nuti, London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J. (1983). Theories of value, output and employment. In J. Eatwell & M. Milgate (Eds.), Keynes’s economics and the theory of value and distribution (pp. 93–128). London: Duckworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fan, Y.-K. (1983). On the rate of profit in the Ricardo-Dmitriev-Sraffa models. Atlantic Economic Journal, 11(2), 97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. (1970). Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the theory of distribution. The Review of Economic Studies, 37(3), 407–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. (1984). Value and distribution in the classical economists and Marx. Oxford Economic Papers, 36(2), 291–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. (1998). Sraffa, Piero. In H. D. Kurz & N. Salvadori (Eds.), The Elgar companion to classical economics L-Z (pp. 391–399). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1976). Use of normalized general co-ordinates in linear value and distribution theory. In K. R. Polenske & J. V. Skolka (Eds.), Advances in input-output analysis (pp. 581–602). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalman, R. E. (1963). Mathematical description of linear dynamical systems. Journal of the Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics on Control, 1(2), 152–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D. (2014). The ‘standpoint of the old classical economists’. In Heterodoxy in economics: From history to pluralism. Festschrift in honour of John King. http://www.vu.edu.au/sites/default/files/cses/pdfs/kurz-paper.pdf. Accessed 12 Dec 2014.

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (1995). Theory of production. A long-period analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (1998). Understanding ‘classical’ economics. Studies in long-period theory. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (2002). One theory or two? Walras’s critique of Ricardo. In H. D. Kurz & N. Salvadori (Eds.) (2007), Interpreting classical economics. Studies in long-period analysis (pp. 53–78). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (2015). Classical economics after Sraffa. Paper presented at the 19th European Society for the History of Economic Thought Conference, 14–16 May 2015, Roma Tre University, Italy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luenberger, D. G. (1979). Introduction to dynamic systems. Theory, models, and applications. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, C. D. (2001). Matrix analysis and applied linear algebra. New York: Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgate, M., & Stimson, S. C. (2011). After Adam Smith: A century of transformation in politics and political economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mühlpfordt, W. (1895). Karl Marx und die durchschnittsprofitrate. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 10(65), 92–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panico, C. (1988). Interest and profit in the theories of value and distribution. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. L. (1959–1960). A mathematical formulation of the Ricardian system. The Review of Economic Studies, 27(2), 78–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. L. (1966). Changes in the rate of profit and switches of techniques. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(4), 503–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. L. (1981). On the Ricardian theory of value: A note. The Review of Economic Studies, 48(4), 673–675.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pivetti, M. (1991). An essay on money and distribution. Basingstoke: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. (1815). An essay on the influence of a low price of corn on the profits of stock, with remarks on Mr Malthus’ two last publications. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1953–1954). Prices of factors and goods in general equilibrium. The Review of Economic Studies, 21(1), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1975). Review of V.K. Dmitriev’s Economic essays on value, competition and utility. Journal of Economic Literature, 13(2), 491–495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities. Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1979a). Trade amongst growing economies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (Ed.). (1979b). Fundamental issues in trade theory. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1994). ‘Perverse’ behaviour in a ‘one commodity’ model. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 18(3), 299–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1998). Classical economics and marginalism. In H. D. Kurz & N. Salvadori (Eds.), The Elgar companion to classical economics A-K (pp. 117–121). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2010). Competing schools of economic thought. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2011). Economic theory in historical perspective. Journal of Economic Analysis, 2(1), 32–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walras, L. ([1874–1877] 1954). Elements of pure economics (trans: Jaffé, W). London: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willke, H. (1993). Systemtheorie. Eine Einführung in die Grundprobleme der Theorie sozialer Systeme. Stuttgart: Gustav Fischer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mariolis, T., Tsoulfidis, L. (2016). Old and Modern Classical Economics. In: Modern Classical Economics and Reality. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 2. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55004-4_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics