Skip to main content

How Does Overconfidence Affect Asset Pricing, Volatility, and Volume?

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Advances in Computational Social Science

Part of the book series: Agent-Based Social Systems ((ABSS,volume 11))

Abstract

Overconfidence is one of the most important characteristics of traders. In the past decade, theoretical approaches have paid much attention to this topic and obtained significant results. However, they heavily rely on specific assumptions regarding the characteristics of traders as well as the market environments. Most importantly, they only consider the market with a few types of traders. None of them is built upon a truly heterogeneous-agent framework . This paper develops an agent-based financial market . Each trader adopts a genetic programming learning method to form his expectations regarding the future. The overconfidence level of each trader is modeled as the degree of underestimation of the conditional variance. Based on this framework, we examine how traders’ overconfidence affects the market by analyzing the results regarding market volatility, price distortion, and trading volume.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The benefits of agent-based modeling in economics and finance are described in [23, 36] in depth.

  2. 2.

    Simon [33] points out that the definition of rationality should consider prediction and the formation of expectations under uncertainty if the assumptions of perfect foresight are discarded.

  3. 3.

    Research such as that of [10, 39–42] adopts this approach.

  4. 4.

    For example, K = 1,12,52,250 represent the number of trading periods measured by the units of a year, month, week, and day, respectively.

  5. 5.

    With this kind of functional form, the traders are still able to take a chance on the martingale hypothesis when f i, t  = 0. The form employed in [8] shares the same merit. Although we agree that it is reasonable to also allow the traders to separately form their expectations about prices and dividends, a multi-objective GP design that aims to accommodate this bipartite learning may be, at the current stage, too complicated to establish an intuitive causal link between price dynamics and individual expectations. Even the models which assume more classic frameworks, like those proposed by Brock and Hommes [5] or the SF-ASM, still somehow simplify the formations of traders’ expectations.

  6. 6.

    For more details about applying the GP to the evolution of function formation, the readers are recommended to refer to Appendix A in [42].

  7. 7.

    A similar design was used in [3, 24].

  8. 8.

    Technically speaking, we may adjust the value of the parameter to achieve the same effects of the parameter shown in Eq. (8.6); however, λ and γ have their own implications. λ describes a trader’s risk preference, while γ measures the level of a trader’s overconfidence, which is not related to his risk preference.

  9. 9.

    Refer to [3], pp. 40–41.

References

  1. Allen WD, Evans DA (2005) Bidding and overconfidence in experimental financial markets. J Behav Finance 6:108–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Anufriev M, Panchenko V (2009) Asset prices, traders’ behavior and market design. J Econ Dyn Control 33:1073–1090

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Arthur WB, Holland J, LeBaron B, Palmer R, Tayler P (1997) Asset pricing under endogenous expectations in an artificial stock market. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf S, Lane D (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Addison-Wesley, Reading, pp 15–44

    Google Scholar 

  4. Benos AV (1998) Aggressiveness and survival of overconfident traders. J Financ Mark 1:353–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Brock WA, Hommes CH (1998) Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 22:1235–1274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Brock WA, Lakonishok J, LeBaron B (1992) Simple technical trading rules and the stochastic properties of stock returns. J Finance 47:1731–1764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Campbell JY, Shiller R (1988) The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Rev Financ Stud 1:195–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Chen S-H, Yeh C-H (2001) Evolving traders and the business school with genetic programming: a new architecture of the agent-based artificial stock market. J Econ Dyn Control 25:363–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Cheng PYK (2007) The trader interaction effect on the impact of overconfidence on trading performance: an empirical study. J Behav Finance 8:59–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Chiarella C, Iori G (2002) A simulation analysis of the microstructure of double auction markets. Quant Finance 2:346–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Daniel K, Hirshleifer D, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. J Finance 53:1839–1885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. De Long JB, Shleifer A, Summers LH, Waldmann RJ (1991) The survival of noise traders in financial markets. J Bus 64:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Deaves R, Lüders E, Schröder M (2010) The dynamics of overconfidence: evidence from stock market forecasters. J Econ Behav Organ 75:402–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Gervais S, Odean T (2001) Learning to be overconfident. Rev Financ Stud 14:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Glaser M, Weber M (2007) Overconfidence and trading volume. Geneva Risk Insur Rev 32:1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Grinblatt M, Keloharju M (2009) Sensation seeking, overconfidence, and trading activity. J Finance 64:549–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. He X-Z, Li Y (2007) Power-law behaviour, heterogeneity, and trend chasing. J Econ Dyn Control 31:3396–3426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Hirshleifer D, Luo GY (2001) On the survival of overconfident traders in a competitive securities market. J Financ Mark 4:73–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Kirman A (2006) Heterogeneity in economics. J Econ Interact Coord 1:89–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Kogan L, Ross SA, Wang J, Westerfield MM (2006) The price impact and survival of irrational traders. J Finance 61:195–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Kyle AS (1985) Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53:1315–1335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Kyle AS, Wang FA (1997) Speculation duopoly with agreement to disagree: can overconfidence survive the market test? J Finance 52:2073–2090

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. LeBaron B (2006) Agent-based computational finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1187–1233

    Google Scholar 

  24. LeBaron B, Arthur WB, Palmer R (1999) Time series properties of an artificial stock market. J Econ Dyn Control 23:1487–1516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Levy M, Levy H, Solomon S (2000) Microscopic simulation of financial markets: from investor behavior to market phenomena. Academic, New York

    Google Scholar 

  26. Lo AW, MacKinlay AC (1988) Stock prices do not follow random walks: evidence from a simple specification test. Rev Financ Stud 1:41–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Lovric M, Kaymak U, Spronk J (2010) Modeling investor sentiment and overconfidence in an agent-based stock market. Human Syst Manag 29:89–101

    Google Scholar 

  28. Neely C, Weller P, Dittmar R (1997) Is technical analysis in the foreign exchange market profitable? A genetic programming approach. J Financ Quant Anal 32:405–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Odean T (1998) Volume, volatility, price, and profit when all traders are above average. J Finance 53:1887–1934

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Pellizzari P, Westerhoff F (2009) Some effects of transaction taxes under different microstructures. J Econ Behav Organ 72:850–863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Scheinkman JA, Xiong W (2003) Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. J Polit Econ 111:1183–1219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Simon H (1957) Models of man. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  33. Simon H (1959) Theories of decision-making in economics and behavioral science. Am Econ Rev 49:253–283

    Google Scholar 

  34. Statman M, Thorley S, Vorkink K (2006) Investor overconfidence and trading volume. Rev Financ Stud 19:1531–1565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Takahashi H, Terano T (2003) Agent-based approach to investors’ behavior and asset price fluctuation in financial markets. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 6(3). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/6/3/3.html

  36. Tesfatsion L (2006) Agent-based computational economics: a constructive approach to economic theory. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 831–880

    Google Scholar 

  37. Tversky A, Kahneman D (1974) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185:1124–1131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Westerhoff F (2003) Speculative markets and the effectiveness of price limits. J Econ Dyn Control 28:493–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Yang J (2002) The efficiency of an artificial double auction stock market with neural learning agents. In: Chen S-H (ed) Evolutionary computation in economics and finance. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp 85–105

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  40. Yeh C-H (2007) The role of intelligence in time series properties. Comput Econ 30:95–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Yeh C-H (2008) The effects of intelligence on price discovery and market efficiency. J Econ Behav Organ 68:613–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Yeh C-H, Yang C-Y (2010) Examining the effectiveness of price limits in an artificial stock market. J Econ Dyn Control 34:2089–2108

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for the useful comments received from two anonymous referees. The research support from NSC Grant no. 98-2410-H-155-021 is also gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chia-Hsuan Yeh .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer Japan

About this paper

Cite this paper

Yeh, CH., Yang, CY. (2014). How Does Overconfidence Affect Asset Pricing, Volatility, and Volume?. In: Chen, SH., Terano, T., Yamamoto, R., Tai, CC. (eds) Advances in Computational Social Science. Agent-Based Social Systems, vol 11. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-54847-8_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics