Skip to main content

Technical Progress and Economies of Scale: Concept of Holotheticity

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Symmetry and Economic Invariance

Part of the book series: Advances in Japanese Business and Economics ((AJBE,volume 1))

  • 678 Accesses

Abstract

Economists are interested in returns to scale for three reasons. First, the equilibrium of an industry is dependent on the nature of its technology. Next, growth theorists, while attributing most of the growth in per capita output to factors other than the increase in capital intensity, are not able to agree whether productivity increases should be modelled as arising from technological change or scale effects. Finally, econometricians recognize the problems in identifying the two sources of productivity in any empirical study.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We can think of differentiation of a function f(x) with respect to x as application of an operator \(\frac{d} {dx}\) to the function f( ⋅); \(f^{\prime} = \left ( \frac{d} {dx}\right )f(x)\). Then second and higher order differentiation of the function can be viewed as repeated application of the operator to the function; \(f^{\prime\prime} = \left ( \frac{d} {dx}\right )\left ( \frac{d} {dx}\right )f(x)\). Notice that the infinitesimal operator is here the linear combination of two partial differential operators.

References

  • Arnord, K.J. (1973). Rawls’ principle of just saving. Swedish Journal of Economics, 75, 323–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Afriat, S.N. (1984). The true index. In A. Ingham, & A.M. Ulph (Eds.), Demand, equilibrium and trade: essays in honor of Ivor Pearce. London: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R.G.D. (1975). Index numbers in theory and practice. London: Macmillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, V.I. (1973). Ordinary differential equations. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, V.I. (1989). Mathematical methods of classical mechanics. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, K.S. (1975). Cost of living index numbers. New York: Marcel Dekker.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowley, A.L. (1928). Notes on index numbers. Economic Journal, 38, 216–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, S. (1939). A study on the pure theory of production, Stockholm economic studies, no. 9. London: P.S. King & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clapham, J.H. (1922a). Of empty economic boxes. Economic Journal, 32, 305–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clapham, J.H. (1922b). The economic boxes: a rejoinder. Economic Journal, 32, 560–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, A. (1931). An introduction to the Lie theory of one-parameter groups. Boston, MA: Heath.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R. (1992). Duality and modern economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Darrough, M.N., & Southey, C. (1977). Duality in consumer theory made simple: the revealing of Roy’s identity. Canadian Journal of Economics, 10, 307–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., & Muelbauer, J. (1980). Economics and consumer behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W.E. (1981). The economic theory of index numbers: a survey. In A. Deaton (Ed.), Essays in the theory and measurement of consumer behaviour in honour of Sir Richard Stone. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W.E. (1982). Duality approaches to microeconomic theory. In K.J. Arrow, & M.D. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics, vol. II (pp. 535–599). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W.E. (1987). Index numbers. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The new palgrave: a dictionary of economics. London: Macmillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dirac, P.A.M. (1958). The priniciples of quantum mechanics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A.K. (1976). The theory of equilibrium growth. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorfman, R., Samuelson, P.A., & Solow, R.M. (1958). Linear programming and economic analysis. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, H.M. (1994). Advanced calculus: a differential forms approach. Boston: Birkhauser.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G.C. (1930). Mathematical introduction to economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feynman, R.P., Leighton, R.B., & Sands, M. (1964). Feynman lectures in physics. Massachusetts: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1922). The making of index numbers. Boston: Houghton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1983). Foundations of space-time theories: relativity physics and philosophy of science. NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. (1936). Annual surveys of general economic theory: the problem of index numbers. Econometrica, 4, 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. (1965). Theory of production. Chicago: Rand-McNally.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gelfand, I.M., & Fomin, S.V. (1963). Calculus of variations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, S.M., & Uzawa, H. (1964). A note on seperability in demand analysis. Econometrica, 32, 387–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanoch, G. (1975). Production or demand models with direct or indirect implicit addictivity. Econometrica, 43, 395–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. (1946). Value and capital, 2nd edn. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. (1969). Direct and indirect addictivity. Econometrica, 37, 353–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker, H.S. (1960). Addicitive preferences. Econometrica, 28, 244–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker, H.S. (1965). A note on self-dual preferences. Econometrica, 33, 797–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, W.E. (1913). The pure theory of utility curves. Economic Journal, 23, 483–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katzner, D.W. (1970). Static demand theory. New York: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, M.C., & Long, N.V. (1982). On evaluation of social income in a dynamic economy: variations on the Samuelsonian theme. In G.R. Feiwel (Ed.), Samuelson and neoclassical economics. Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. (1930). A treatise on money. London: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, M. (1972). Mathematical thought from ancient to modern times. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konus, A.A. (1939). The problem of the true index of the cost of living (English translation of 1924 article). Econometrica, 7, 10–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, T.C. (1967). Intertemporal distribution and ‘optimal’ aggregate economic growth. In Ten economic studies in the tradition of Irving Fisher. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lau, L.J. (1969). Duality and the structure of utility preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 1, 374–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, L.J. (1978). Applications of profit functions. In M. Fuss, & D. Mc-Fadden (Eds.), Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holand.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics: an introductory volume. London: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minhas, B.S. (1963). An international comparison of factor costs and factor use. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olver, P.J. (1986). Applications of Lie groups to differential equations. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Olver, P.J. (1995). Equivalence, invariants, and symmetry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, I.F. (1962). The end of the golden age in Solovia. American Economic Review, 52, 1088–1097.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E.S. (1987). Golden rule. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Neuman (Eds.), New pelgrave: a dictionary of economics. London: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A.C. (1922). Empty economic boxes: a reply. Economic Journal, 32, 16–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak, R.A. (1971). Additive utility functions and linear engel curves. The Review of Economic Studies, 37, 401–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richter, M.K. (1966). Invariance axioms and economic indexes. Econometrica, 34, 739–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, D.H. (1924). Those empty economic boxes. Economic Journal, 34, 16–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russell, R.R. (1964). The empirical evaluation of theoretically plausible demand functions, Ph.D. Dissertation. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1938). A note on the pure theory of consumer’s behavior. Economical, 5, 62–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1950). The problem of integrability in utility theory. Economica, 17, 355–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samueslon, P.A. (1961). The evaluation of social income: capital formation and wealth. In F.A. Lutz, & D.C. Hague (Eds.), Theory of capital. London: McMillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1965). A catenary turnpike theorem involving consumption and the golden rule. American Economic Review, 55, 486–496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1967). Turnpike refutation of the golden rule in the welfare-maximizing many year plan. In K. Shell (Ed.), Essays in the theory of optimal economic growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1969). Corrected formulation of direct and indirect additivity. Econometrica, 37, 355–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1970). Law of conservation of capital-output ratio in closed von Neumann systems. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, Applied Mathematical Science, 67, 1477–1479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A., & Solow, R.M. (1956). A complete capital model involving heterogeneous captial goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 537–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A., & Swamy, S. (1974). Invariant economic index numbers and canaoncial duality: survey and synthesis. American Economic Review, 64, 566–593.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1974). On the separable class of non-homothetic CES functions. Economic Studies Quarterly, 25, 42–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1976). Self-dual preferences. Econometrica, 44, 1017–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1977a). Homothetic and non-homothetic CES functions. American Economic Review, 67, 559–569.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1977b). The implicit formulation and non-homothetic structure of utility functions. In H. Albach, E. Helmstadter, & R. Henn (Eds.), Qualitative wirtshcaftsfors chung: W. Krelle zum 60. Geburstag. Tubingen: Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1981). Theory of technical change and economic invariance: application of Lie groups. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1985). The invariance principle and income-wealth conservation laws. Journal of Econometrics, 30, 365–389. Reprint (1990) In R. Sato, & R. Ramchandran (Eds.), Conservation laws and symmetry: applications to economics and finance (pp.71–106). Norwell, MA: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R. (1990). The invariance principle and income-wealth conservation laws. In R. Sato, & R. Ramachandran, Conservation laws and symmetry. Boston:Kluwer

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R., & Matsushita, M. (1989). Estimation of self-dual demand functions: an international comaprison. In R. Sato, & T. Negishi (Eds.), Developments in Japanese economics. Tokyo: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, R., & Ramachandran, R. (1974). Models of optimal endogenous technical progress, scale effect, and duality of production functions, Discussion Paper, Department of Economics, Brown University, Providence, RI

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, E. (1934). Theorie der production. Vienna: J. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shepherd, R.W. (1953). Cost and production fucntions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R.M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregte production function. Review of Economic Statistics, 39, 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silberberg, E. (1990). The structure of economics: a mathematical analysis. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1926). The laws of return under competitive conditions. Economic Journal, 36, 535–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephani, H, & MacCullum, M. (1989). Differential equations: their solution using symmetries. Cambridge: Cambridge Unviversity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1961). Economic problems in measuring changes in productivity. Output, input, and productivity, measurement, conference on research in income and wealth (pp. 47–63). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanek, J. (1968). Maximal economic growth. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H.R. (1984). Microeconomic analysis. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M.L. (1976). On the welfare significance of national product in a dynamic economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 156–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitaker, J.K. (1990). Marshall’s theories of competitive price. In R.M. Tullberg (Ed.), Alfred Marshall in retrospect (pp. 29–48). Vermont: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoglam, I. (1988). Felix Klein and Sophus Lie: evolution of the idea of symmetry in the nineteenth century. Boston: Birkhauser.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zellner, A., & Revanker, N.S. (1969). Generalized production functions. Review of Economic Studies, 36, 241–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer Japan

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sato, R., Ramachandran, R.V. (2014). Technical Progress and Economies of Scale: Concept of Holotheticity. In: Symmetry and Economic Invariance. Advances in Japanese Business and Economics, vol 1. Springer, Tokyo. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-54430-2_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics