Skip to main content
  • 544 Accesses

Abstract

All markets need institutions in order to function properly. From the simplest exchange transaction that is governed by the rules of business, cultural norms or traditions to the most complex decision-making procedure that involves strategic uncertainty and limited information, our behavior is shaped by formal and informal institutions that help to facilitate order in daily social and economic interactions and reduce uncertainty in exchange. While an explicit acknowledgement of this fundamental role of institutions in socio-economic life might seem superfluous and obvious to the reader with a non-economics background,188 it is a fact that the prevailing neoclassical theory treats institutions as a highly abstract matter as well as exogenously given, and thus inconsequential, in economic processes. The New Institutional Economics (NIE) attempts to address this shortcoming from an economic science’s point of view. The final part of this chapter will, therefore, review some of the main ideas of this theory, along with complementary, yet different, approaches suggested by two NIE scholars — Douglass North and Oliver Williamson — that are relevant to the analysis at hand. This process will serve to highlight the role and importance of institutions in general as well as their significance for FDI government competition in particular.

Unless the economics scholar is acquainted with the ideas of the German Ordo-Liberalist School which is associated with the writings of Walter Eucken, Alexander Rüstow, Wilhelm Röpke, Franz Böhm, and the Freiburg School. Although the movement was conceived in the late 1920s as a response to the constitutional and economic crisis of the Weimar Republic, its core ideas (i.e., that a certain institutional framework or social and political “order” is essential in achieving economic efficiency to produce individual freedom and liberty) became particularly influential in the founding of West-Germany’s post-World War II “social market economy”.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. The term “New Institutional Economics” was coined by Oliver Williamson who first used it in his publication “Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications” (WILLIAMSON, 1975).

    Google Scholar 

  2. KASPER/ STREIT (1998), p. 34.

    Google Scholar 

  3. These include, inter alia, Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz (property rights approach — ALCHIAN/ DEMSETZ, 1972); Oliver Williamson (transaction cost economics — WILLIAMSON, 1975, 1986); and Douglas North (institutional environment and institutional change — NORTH, 1984, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  4. See FURUBOTN/ RICHTER, 1997, p. 2. The demarcation between the two fields is not as clear cut, and the intellectual debate whether or not the NIE is part of the neoclassical theory or a separate strand is still underway (see FURUBOTN/ RICHTER, 1997, p. 435).

    Google Scholar 

  5. See NORTH (1992), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  6. The concept of bounded rationality was introduced by Herbert Simon (see SIMON, 1957).

    Google Scholar 

  7. NORTH (1992), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  8. DAHLMANN (1979), p. 147.

    Google Scholar 

  9. MATTHEWS (1986), p. 903.

    Google Scholar 

  10. An excellent overview on NIE theories can be found in FURUBOTN/ RICHTER (1997); KASPER/ STREIT (1998); and RUTHERFORD (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  11. WILLIAMSON (1998), p. 75.

    Google Scholar 

  12. NORTH (1992), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  13. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 598.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Bounded rationality prevents the existence of “complete contingent contract” (WILLIAMSON, 2000, p. 601).

    Google Scholar 

  15. OSTROM (1995), p. 582.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Man-made is to be understood in Hayek’s sense of “The result of human action but not of human design” (HAYEK, 1967, p. 96).

    Google Scholar 

  17. NORTH (1992), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  18. VOIGT (2002), p. 36.

    Google Scholar 

  19. VOIGT (2002), p. 37.

    Google Scholar 

  20. VOIGT (2002) also points out that “social sanctioning” is not costless and, due to the collective action problem, will only happen if the sanctioner expects a repeat situation to occur. The most common effect of “social sanctioning” is on the reputation of the sanctionee.

    Google Scholar 

  21. NORTH (1990), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  22. COLEMAN (1974) distinguishes between individual actors, who wish to maximize their individual interests, and corporate actors, who act on the behalf of some group or collectivity.

    Google Scholar 

  23. KASPER/ STREIT (1998), p. 98.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See VOIGT (2002), p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 596.

    Google Scholar 

  26. See MANTZAVINOS (2001), p. 83.

    Google Scholar 

  27. KASPER/ STREIT (1998), p. 185.

    Google Scholar 

  28. See FURUBOTN/ PEJOVICH (1972), p. 139.

    Google Scholar 

  29. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 598. He calls this also “first-order economizing”.

    Google Scholar 

  30. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 599.

    Google Scholar 

  31. This is subsequently called “second-order economizing” (see WILLIAMSON, 2000, p. 599).

    Google Scholar 

  32. See NORTH (1992), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See NORTH (1986), p. 231.

    Google Scholar 

  34. See NORTH (1990), p. 84.

    Google Scholar 

  35. North’s efficiency criteria is not the Pareto-Optimum of the Welfare Economics (which explicitly neglects institutional factors) but institutional “adaptive efficiency”, i.e., the “willingness of a society to acquire knowledge and learning, to induce innovation, to undertake risk and creative activity of all sorts, as well as to resolve problems and bottlenecks of the society through time” (NORTH, 1994, p. 1). His choosing of economic growth rates as an efficiency measure is problematic.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See NORTH (1990), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Path dependency is a result of increasing returns that reinforce the direction once a path is chosen (see NORTH, 1990, p. 112).

    Google Scholar 

  38. North details the game-theoretic framework using the Prisoner’s Dilemma-Model (see NORTH, 1990, p. 13). A more comprehensive presentation of the game-theoretic logic will be provided in sub-Chapter 4.3.1 of this dissertation.

    Google Scholar 

  39. NORTH (1990), p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See NORTH (1990), p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  41. NORTH (1986), p. 233.

    Google Scholar 

  42. COASE (1937), p. 390.

    Google Scholar 

  43. WILLIAMSON (1985), p. 19. Williamson himself only loosely defines transaction costs as “costs of running the system” (WILLIAMSON, 1985, p. 18), which is a reference to ARROWS (1969), p. 48.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See WILLIAMSON (1975), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See WILLIAMSON (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  46. SIMON (1957), p. 241.

    Google Scholar 

  47. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 601.

    Google Scholar 

  48. MEYER (1998), p. 92.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Williamson maintains that opportunism is a necessary condition for internalization to occur. For a discussion of this argument see MEYER (1998), p. 99.

    Google Scholar 

  50. WILLIAMSON (1985), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See VOIGT (2002), p. 106.

    Google Scholar 

  52. WILLIAMSON (1985), p. 48.

    Google Scholar 

  53. See WILLIAMSON (1985), p. 79.

    Google Scholar 

  54. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 601.

    Google Scholar 

  55. WILLIAMSON (2000), p. 601.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See VOIGT (2002), p. 111.

    Google Scholar 

  57. WILLIAMSON (1985), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  58. See for example OECD (2002); CHAN-LEE/ AHN (2001); WILHELMS (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  59. See MEYER (1998), pp. 87–88.

    Google Scholar 

  60. See MUDAMBI (2002), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See KUHN (1962), p. 36; MEYER (1998), p. 87.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See OMAN (2000), p. 107.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See OMAN (2000), p. 107.

    Google Scholar 

  64. OECD (2002), p. 25.

    Google Scholar 

  65. The presentation in Figure 4 follows the OECD (2002) approach in a sense that it considers only counties with cumulative FDI inflows of less than US$ 60 billion (1995–2000) in order to isolate the effect of top-performing industrialized countries which also ranked the highest on the institutional governance index. For details see Annex Table A-2 and A-3 on country data and correlation matrix. For a similar presentation with different FDI data see OECD (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  66. WILHELMS (1998), in: Abstract.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See WILHELMS (1998), p. 41.

    Google Scholar 

  68. DISDIER/ MAYER (2004), p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  69. The terminology used in this paragraph as well as in Table 4 is based on an article by CHARLTON/ CHRISTIANSEN/ OMAN (2002) which use these labels in a different context to describe welfare effects in competition between national and subnational levels.

    Google Scholar 

  70. As VOIGT (2002) has rightly pointed out, rational choice is one of the assumptions that the NIE first abandoned, thus, game-theoretic scenarios only have limited compatibility with NIE theories.

    Google Scholar 

  71. The assumptions are that TC(I) involve a certain amount of fixed costs (FC), i.e., costs of setting-up the operation in a foreign country, and increase at a lower rate than TC(E) due to internalization advantages depicted in the above graph through different slopes of the two curves. Project benefits (PB) are thought to occur when project revenues minus the combined production and transaction costs are positive, i.e., R − (TC + PC) > 0. See MEYER (1998), p. 89 for details on this equation.

    Google Scholar 

  72. See also MEYER (1998), p. 100 who identifies five distinct factors that moderate TCs, namely common governance, corporate culture, experience, physical distance and sources of funding.

    Google Scholar 

  73. WILLIAMSON (1998), p. 76.

    Google Scholar 

  74. See MEYER (1998), p. 96. See also WILLIAMSON (1975, 1985).

    Google Scholar 

  75. See MEYER (1998), p. 96.

    Google Scholar 

  76. They also influence external transaction costs in the same direction so the net shift between externalization and internalization is unclear and not further discussed here as the focus is on the potentially FDI expanding effect of government policies. For the discussion of the debate about FDI as substituting or complementing trade see, for example, GRAHAM (1995, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  77. See DOYLE/ VAN WINJBERGEN (1994), pp. 211–212.

    Google Scholar 

  78. See MUDAMBI (1999), pp. 73–75.

    Google Scholar 

  79. See UNCTAD (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  80. This argument builds on Mudambi’s statement that “governments may prefer support schemes that appear to be more expensive, but have better incentive or risk-sharing implications.” (MUDAMBI, 1999, p. 75).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag | GWV Fachverlage GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2006). The New Institutional Economics Theory. In: Locational Tournaments in the Context of the EU Competitive Environment. DUV. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-8350-9109-2_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics