Skip to main content

Regional Integration and FDI Competition

  • Chapter
  • 474 Accesses

Abstract

The process of current and future enlargement of the EU adds another dynamic element to the challenges facing the Commission in reforming the existing framework for FDI competition. Here, the balancing act for accession countries and the EU alike is to align the (mostly non-conforming) FDI policies and instruments in the new member countries with the EU competition Aquis, while at the same time allowing the newcomers to maintain a competitive framework for FDI. An effective solution to this issue will depend both on substance as well as the overall approach applied to the process of policy integration. The following sub-chapter will address these issues from an institutional point of view, backed by empirical data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Specifically, these criteria include (i) stability of institutions guaranteeing democracy, the rule of law, human rights and protection of minorities; (ii) existence of a functioning market economy as well as the capacity to cope with competitive pressure and market forces within the Union; (iii) ability to take on the obligations of membership including adherence to the aims of political, economic and monetary union (see EU, 2004a).

    Google Scholar 

  2. See UNCTAD (2003a), pp. 22–23.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 64. By the end of 2002, CEE countries had concluded more than 700 BITs and over 600 DTTs, which account for more than 33 and 27 percent of the world’s BITs and DTTs, respectively.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 64; EU (2003), p. 122.

    Google Scholar 

  5. See EU (2004), p. 46.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See EU (2003b), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  7. See, for example, SINN (1992); SIEBERT/ KOOP (1993, 1994); STREIT (1996); STREIT/KIWITT (1999); KLODT (1999); SIEBERT (2000); CASPERS (2004) for a detailed discussion.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See DÜMLER (2000), p. 180.

    Google Scholar 

  9. See WOHLGEMUTH (1995), p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  10. See SIEBERT/ KOOP (1994) for a detailed overview of both lines of arguments.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See KLODT (1999), p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  12. For an opposing view concerning the effectiveness of policy regulation vis-à-vis spillover effects see, for example, SIEBERT (1994). However, the variable “international spillovers” can easily be substituted with “strategic behavior” of individual states, which has been more readily accepted as having a potentially negative impact on competition, and thus can be used as case for international coordination in the area of competition policy (see SIEBERT/ KOOP, 1994, p. 613).

    Google Scholar 

  13. See SIEBERT (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  14. SIEBERT/ KOOP (1994), p. 614.

    Google Scholar 

  15. STEIN/ DAUDE (2001) used a variety of institutional factors appearing in (i) KAUFMANN/ KRAY/ ZOIDO-LOBATON (1999); (ii) POLITICAL RISK SERVICES (1995); and (iii) WORLD BANK (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  16. STEIN/ DAUDE (2001), p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  17. “Embeddedness” here refers to the NIE distinction between Level 2 and 3 institutions, and the fact that both are conditionally interlinked with each other. Therefore, any adjustment in either one of them should be made in a “slow, molecular, deliberative way” (WILLIAMSON, 2000, p. 610).

    Google Scholar 

  18. See UNCTAD (2003), p. 63.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See RAINES/ BROWN (1999), p. 110.

    Google Scholar 

  20. For a more comprehensive model to determine the role of a wider variety of institutional factors and countries in a full fledged gravity model see, for example, STEIN/ DAUDE (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  21. A number of recent studies have used ICRG rankings as an indicator of property rights as well as measure of broader institutional quality in general, see, for example, TOBIN/ ROSE-ACKERMAN (2004); HALLWARD-DRIEMEIER (2003); RODRIK/ SUBRAMANIAN/ TREBBI (2002); STEIN/ DAUDE (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  22. FDI stocks are used here as an indicator because they better capture the “absolute” exposure that a firm may want to have in a given country, and, thus, also the changes in the “relative beauty” of a location over time (see STEIN/ DAUDE, 2001, p. 10).

    Google Scholar 

  23. See COHEN/ COHEN/ WEST/ AIKEN (2003), pp. 221–222. In addition, transformations also serve to eliminate heteroscedasticity and to normalize residuals.

    Google Scholar 

  24. STEIN/ DAUDE (2001), p. 17.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See MALLYA/ KUKULKA/ JENSEN (2004), p. 123.

    Google Scholar 

  26. SIEBERT/ KOOP (1994), p. 614.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See DOYLE/ WIJNBERGEN (1994), pp. 211–212.

    Google Scholar 

  28. They can also be an instrument to overcome certain agglomeration patterns associated with a “follow-the-leader” (KNICKERBOCKER, 1973) strategy (see CHARLTON, 2003, p. 10).

    Google Scholar 

  29. See EU (2000) pp. 14–15.

    Google Scholar 

  30. See EU (2000), p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  31. See BIAC (2002), p. l.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See Wishlade, in RAINES/ BROWN, (1999), p. 110

    Google Scholar 

  33. See BIAC (2002), p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag | GWV Fachverlage GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2006). Regional Integration and FDI Competition. In: Locational Tournaments in the Context of the EU Competitive Environment. DUV. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-8350-9109-2_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics