Skip to main content

The Evolution of Moral Science: Economic Rationality in the Complex Social System

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Complexities of Production and Interacting Human Behaviour
  • 605 Accesses

Abstract

Economics in the early 20th Century established distributive justice as the marginal productivity theory of income distribution. As the system has evolved, however, the distributive principle has been lost as a result of the structural change of the production process. Faced with “casino capitalism” or the “winner-take-all” society, instead of the classic distributive justice, a lottery system dominates income distribution. Orthodox economics prefers a set of particular rationalities, e.g., the so-called game theoretic views, instead of the general rationality. These particular rationalities are examined in some detail and their failures are argued. Rationality, either in general or in a particular form, is not to be regarded as a panacea in the complex socio-economic system.

This paper proposes the use of the utilitarianism of heterogeneous interacting agents. This new utilitarianism may easily be applied to the transition rates of the master equations, i.e., the probabilistic Markov process. Furthermore, a new method to reconstruct economic science is also suggested: constructing methods derived directly from new ideas in statistical physics and combinatorial stochastic process.

In sum, individualistic rationality must be replaced with the utilitarianism of heterogeneous interacting agents. In this new framework, solidarity formation among the heterogeneous interacting agents should be the most important matter. Finally, a deeper consideration on the utilitarianism of heterogeneous agents is explored.

This paper is mainly based on the paper “Evolution der Sittenlehre über Wirtschaftliche Rationalität im Komplexen Sozialsystem” presented at 3. Wissenschaftliches Symposium, Deutsch-Japanische Gesselschaft für integrative Wissenschaft, Montag, 30. Oktober 2006, Museum Koenig, Bonn, though this is not the same in is contents. The author is very grateful for Abt Nissho Takeuchi, the German–Japan Society for Integrative Science, Bonn, and the Daiseion-ji, Wipperfürth for generous permission of this material.

Reprinted from Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 4(2), Aruka, Y., The Evolution of Moral Science: Economic Rationality in the Complex Social System, 217–237 (2009). With kind permission from Japan Association for Evolutionary Economics, Tokyo.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The Pareto criterion originally implied that the personal welfare of every agent must not be impaired absolutely.

  2. 2.

    Core is defined as a Pareto optimum within the area of being at least no worse than the initial welfare level.

  3. 3.

    Arthur (1996) depicted this capitalism vividly.

  4. 4.

    Casino capitalism should bring on the “winner-take-all society” if we focus on the distribution side. See Frank and Cook (1995).

  5. 5.

    In the classic case, we called the irreproducible factors like labor or land the factors of production. In modern services production, the concept of labor may evolve.

  6. 6.

    As for the perversities of the joint production, see Schefold (1989). Many orthodox professional economic theorists have made efforts to generalize the mathematical conditions to contain the non-convexity of production and consumption, without paying attention to the possibility of the distributive justice of production.

  7. 7.

    This principle is active in a choice under uncertainty. We take an example of toads croaking. We suppose that the threshold pitch of croaking is set at 6.0, the lowest at 0, the highest at 10. “If only those toads with a pitch below 6.0 bother to croak, toads who remain silent reveal that their pitch is, on the average, significantly higher than 6.0”(Frank 2003, p. 202).

  8. 8.

    See Holland (1992, Chap. 5). It no longer has the aesthetic beauty of dual principles of cost minimization and utility maximization.

  9. 9.

    See Aoki and Yoshikawa (2006).

  10. 10.

    In our example, we set ε = 0.05, and calculated π = 0.75. It then the maximum number is

    10.413 since

    $$ M \le \frac{{\ln \varepsilon }}{{\ln \pi }} = 10.413. $$
  11. 11.

    In order to argue these precisely, according to Weidlich (2000), we need to construct the socio-configuration by employing the personal variables and material variables pertinently specified, also defining the trend and control-parameters, and then the autonomous self-contained probabilistic sub-dynamics on the social system.

  12. 12.

    See Theorem 3.1 of Arthur (1994, Chap. 10, pp.189–190).

  13. 13.

    The numerical simulation of this model continues to be developed by the research group of Mauro Gallegati. See for example Gallegati et al. (2006).

  14. 14.

    See Aoki (2002).

  15. 15.

    “The analyst has to identify those that are likely to explain the choice of the individual. There is no automatic process to perform this identification. The knowledge of the actual application and the data availability plays an important role in this process” Bierlaire (1997, p. 4).

  16. 16.

    As for the classification of dependent games, see Akiyama and Aruka (2006).

References

  • Akiyama E, Aruka Y (2006) Evolution of reciprocal cooperation in the Avatamsaka game. In: Namatame A, Kaizoji T, Aruka Y (eds) The complex networks of economic interactions: essays in agent-based economics and econophysics. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 307–320

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (1996) New approaches to macroeconomic modeling: evolutionary stochastic dynamics, multiple equilibria, and externalities as field effects. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (2002) Modeling aggregate behavior and fluctuations in economics: stochastic views of interacting agents. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M, Yoshikawa H (2006) Reconstructing macroeconomics: a perspective from statistical physics and combinatorial stochastic processes. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur WB (1994) Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur WB (1996) Increasing returns and the new world of business. Harvard Bus Rev 74:100–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Aruka Y (2001) Avatamsaka game structure and experiment on the Web. In: Aruka Y (ed) Evolutionary controversies in economics. Springer, Tokyo, pp 115–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Aumann RJ, Maschler M (1985) Game theoretic analysis of a bankruptcy problem from the Talmud. J Econ Theory 36:195–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellman R (1961) Adaptive control processes: a guided tour. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Bierlaire M (1997) Discrete choice models (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2005) Can self-interest explain cooperation? Evol Inst Econ Rev 2(1):21–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Ewens WJ (1972) The sampling theory of selectively neutral alleles. Theor Popul Biol 3:87–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank R (2003) Microeconomics and behavior, 5th edn. McGraw-Hill, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank R, Cook P (1995) The winner-take-all society. Free, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Levine D (1989) Reputation and equilibrium selection in games with a patient player. Econometrica 57:759–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallegati M, Palestrini A, Delli Gatti E, Scalas E (2006) Aggregation of heterogeneous interacting agents: the variant representative agents framework. J Econ Interact Coord 1:5–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Helbing D (1995) Quantitative sociodynamics: stochastic methods and models of social interaction processes. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Holland JH (1992) Adaptation in natural and artificial systems. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainzer K (2005) Wass sind komplexe Systeme? In: Symposium zur Gr¨undung einer Deutsch-Japanischen Akadmie f¨ur integrative Wissenschaft, 2005 J.H. R¨oll Verlag, pp 37–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitman J (1995) Exchangeable and partially exchangeable random partitions. Probab Theory Relat Field 12:145–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poser H (2005) The prediction problems in the complex sciences. In: Complexity and integrative science. Koyo-Shobo, Kyoto, pp 3–26 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild M (1974) A two-armed bandit theory of market pricing. J Econ Theory 9:185–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schefold B (1989) Mr. Sraffa on joint production and other essays. Unwin Hyman, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider E (1934) Theorie der Produktion. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Weidlich W (2000) Sociodynamics: a systematic approach to mathematical modeling in the social sciences. Harwood Academic Publishers, Amsterdam (The Gordon and Breach Publishing Group). [Reprinted by Taylor and Francis (2002); Paper edition, Dover Publications (2006); Japanese translation, Morikita Shuppan (2007)]

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuji Aruka .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Aruka, Y. (2011). The Evolution of Moral Science: Economic Rationality in the Complex Social System. In: Aruka, Y. (eds) Complexities of Production and Interacting Human Behaviour. Physica, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2618-0_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics