Skip to main content

Profiling the Provision Status of Health-Promoting Public Goods Against AIDS

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 429 Accesses

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

It is well-known that the private provision of public goods results generally in collective underprovision. The same situation seems plausible in the case of combating HIV/AIDS. The desire to intervene effectively has been addressed by a lot of international negotiations. A landmark in international efforts is the Declaration of Commitment on HIV/AIDS (UN 2001). It was adopted at the United Nations General Assembly Special Session in June 2001 (Department of HIV/AIDS Family and Community Health 2003, p. 10). For the first time governments from 189 states gathered to discuss a specific health problem. The Declaration describes the HIV/AIDS epidemic and its effects as well as desired interventions. Basic priorities are educating people, especially the youth; stopping mother-child-transmission; providing treatment to all those who are infected; developing an AIDS vaccine or a cure and alleviating the impacts of HIV/AIDS. Although specific time-bound targets exist for each of those aims, these agreements are not legally binding. Governments cannot be compelled to keep their promises since an enforcing authority is missing. Since autonomous governments primarily consider their national benefits, they fail to take positive cross-border effects into account. As a consequence, an efficient transnational provision level of health measures cannot be provided (Kremer 2006, p. 26; Kaul 2002, p. 27). However, this conclusion is based on the very strong assumption that the sum of individual efforts at the national level equals the global effort. The condition of a summation technology is not valid for every health-promoting public good as we know from Chap. 2.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A more general description of suboptimality based on insufficient incentives can be found in Olsen (1965).

  2. 2.

    For concreteness, governments act on behalf of their citizens.

  3. 3.

    The subsequent analyses concentrate on these three health interventions and thus measures like collecting data for transnational health statistics and developing second-drug lines against HIV also mentioned in Chap. 2 will not be discussed. We explain in Sect. 3.1 why we focus on the three key health-promoting public goods.

  4. 4.

    A simple but successful strategy is Tit-for-Tat which has got attention after the publications of Axelrod (1980a, b). Axelrod invited game theorists to design strategies which do not fail in repeated games. To identify the most successful proposal, a computer competition was simulated in which each submission was tested. Tit-for-Tat which was submitted by Rapoport won. The idea is to cooperate in the first round if the choices of the other are unknown. In the subsequent rounds, previous cooperation is rewarded by cooperation and opportunistic behaviour is answered by becoming opportunistic.

  5. 5.

    Kremer (2006, pp. 34–37) suggests the implementation of a large-scale purchase commitment programme financed by the World Bank to encourage R&D in vaccine research.

  6. 6.

    If private firms do not compete in HIV vaccine research, patent-race games seem less appropriate. Multiple firms spend resources on R&D until one of them makes a discovery. The firm that innovates first will obtain a patent while all other firms will gain nothing.

  7. 7.

    For simplicity the utility function does not include externalities caused by implemented health interventions. For example, the discovery and supply of an HIV vaccine could reduce the provision of curative health activities like treatment with antiretroviral drugs since an infection with HIV could be prevented.

  8. 8.

    For concreteness, a country cannot receive benefits. We suppose that countries possess benevolent governments that act on behalf of their citizens who gain from health measures. Because we have assumed identical individuals, the utility function of a representative individual is represented.

  9. 9.

    A similar figure can be found in Cornes and Sandler (1996, p. 146).

  10. 10.

    This assumption is known as a zero conjecture variation in that sense that each agent regards the behaviour of the other agents as independent of its own (Cornes and Sandler 1984b, p. 371).

  11. 11.

    An analytical investigation of the existence of a Nash equilibrium can be found in Bergstrom et al. (1986, pp. 32–34).

  12. 12.

    This depiction follows the figure in Hirshleifer (1983, p. 375).

  13. 13.

    For the standard result see Hirshleifer (1983, pp. 375–376) as well as Cornes and Sandler (1996, pp. 155–158).

  14. 14.

    The contract curve represents all Pareto-efficient allocations given the price p and the income levels \( {I_i}\ \)for \( i = 1,2 \).

  15. 15.

    The right-hand side of (3.12) is equivalent to the marginal costs MC which are identical for each country \( (M{C_1} = M{C_2}) \).

  16. 16.

    A similar argument can be found in Ihori (2005).

  17. 17.

    We closely follow Ihori (2005). Figure 3.3 is similar to the depiction in Ihori (2005).

  18. 18.

    This is due to the fact that the second constraint also needs to be fulfilled.

  19. 19.

    In order to derive country i's reaction curves we follow Hirshleifer (1985, p. 221) and Ihori (2005). Similar figures can be found in Vicary (1990, p. 379), Hirshleifer (1985, p. 222); as well as Ihori (2005).

  20. 20.

    Reaction curves can be derived as in the benchmark case. However, in the previous analysis we have modified \( {G_{ - i}} \) to receive a reaction curve.

  21. 21.

    Country 1 can reduce its contribution to the public good and can utilise an increasing part of income for private consumption in point A compared to \( B' \).

  22. 22.

    As noted by Hirshleifer (1983, p. 376), the \( 45^\circ \)-line where \( {g_1} = {g_2} \) plays an important role. Country 1 (2) will never provide prophylactic health measures outside of the range \( {g_1} \leqslant {g_2} \) \( ({g_2} \leqslant {g_1}) \). This results from the weakest-link technology.

  23. 23.

    The right-hand side of (3.19) is equivalent to the sum of both countries’ marginal costs \( M{C_1} + M{C_2} \).

  24. 24.

    This is the case which is explained by Hirshleifer (1983).

  25. 25.

    An alternative way of analysing allocative implications of a best-shot aggregation technology can be found in Cornes and Hartley (2007a, pp. 1701–1704). In contrast to the approach of a best response function, they use a replacement function expressing an agent i’s best response as a function of the overall public good provision level G and not of the sum of the best replies of all other agents. For a further characterisation of individual and aggregated replacement functions see Cornes and Hartley (2006) as well as Cornes and Hartley (2007b).

  26. 26.

    This depiction follows the figure in Sonntag (2009a).

  27. 27.

    IAVI is the world’s largest organisation focussing on the development of an AIDS vaccine.

  28. 28.

    Figure 3.8 follows the depiction in Sonntag (2009a).

  29. 29.

    A detailed discussion under which circumstances financial support has to be given to research institutions in the developing world can be found in Chap. 4.

  30. 30.

    The right-hand side of (3.36) will equal country 1's marginal costs \( M{C_1} \) if country 2 is a non-contributor. Hence, there is a difference compared with the summation case where \( M{C_1} = M{C_2} = MR{S_1} + MR{S_2} \).

  31. 31.

    By contrast, in patent races competition in R&D may lead to excessive expenditures on R&D relative to the social optimum where the marginal social return equals the marginal cost. One rationale may be rent-seeking to secure patent protection ahead of other firms. A detailed analysis of the consequences of R&D competition can be found in Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980).

  32. 32.

    A detailed derivation of allocative decisions by taking intergenerative spillovers into account can be found in Sandler (1978).

References

  • Arce, D., & Sandler, T. (2002b). Regional public goods: Typologies, provision, financing, and development assistance. Stockholm: Almkvist and Wiksell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1980a). The effective choice in the Prisoner´s Dilemma. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24, 3–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1980b). More effective choice in the Prisoner´s Dilemma. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24, 379–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conybeare, J., Murdoch, J., & Sandler, T. (1994). Alternative collective-goods models of military alliances: Theory and empirics. Economic Inquiry, 32, 525–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbett, E., et al. (2002). HIV-1/AIDS and the control of other infectious diseases in Africa. The Lancet, 359, 2177–2187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2006). Weak links, good shots and other public good games: Building on BBV (Discussion Paper EDP-0624). Manchester

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2007a). Weak links, good shots and other public good games: building on BBV. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1684–1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2007b). Aggregative public good games. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 9, 201–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984b). The theory of public goods: Non-Nash behaviour. Journal of Public Economic, 23, 367–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1985). The simple analytics of pure public good provision. Economica, 52, 103–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). Uncertainty, industrial structure, and the spreed of R&D. Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Department of HIV/AIDS Family and Community Health. (2003). Global health-sector strategy for HIV/AIDS: 2003–2007. Providing a framework for partnership and action. Geneva: WHO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G., & Hirshleifer, J. (1989). An experimental evaluation of weakest link/best shot models of public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 201–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1983). From weakest-link to best-shot: The voluntary provision ofpublic goods. Public Choice, 41, 371–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1985). From weakest-link to best-shot: Correction. Public Choice, 46, 221–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ihori, T. (2005). Weakest link and best shots. (mimeo).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaul, I. (2002). Profiling the provision status of global public goods. New York: UNDP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaul, I., Grunberg, I., & Stern, M. (1999). Global Public Goods: International co-operation in the 21st century. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, M. (2006). Global public goods in communicable disease control. In Secretariat of the International Task Force on Global Public Goods (Ed.), Expert paper series one: Infectious disease. Stockholm: International Task Force on Global Public Goods.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. (1906). Manuale di economia politica. New York: Augustus M Kelley. Revised and 1971 translated into English as Manual of political economy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramachandran, V., Shah, M. K., & Turner, G. (2006). Does the private sector care about AIDS? Evidence from Investment Climate Surveys in East Africa (Working paper No. 76). Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1978). Interregional and intergenerational spillover awareness. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 25, 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2003). Assessing the optimal provision of public goods. In search of the Holy Grail. In I. Kaul et al. (Eds.), Providing global public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2006). Regional public goods and regional cooperation. In Secretariat of the International Task Force on Global Public Goods (Ed.), Meeting global challenges: International cooperation in the national interest: Cross-cutting issues. Stockholm: Secretariat.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sonntag, D. (2009a). Providing global public goods against AIDS – A public good approach. In D. Duffy & E. Shinnick (Eds.), Public goods, public policy and taxation: An European perspective. Berlin: LIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1999). Knowledge as a global public good. In I. Kaul, I. Grunberg, & M. Stern (Eds.), Global Public Goods: International co-operation in the 21st century. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stillwaggon, E. (2006a). AIDS and the ecology of poverty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. (2004). System reliability and free riding (Working Paper). Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vicary, S. (1990). Transfers and the weakest-link: An extension of Hirshleifer´s analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 43, 375–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wines, M. (2007, 28 January 2007). Virulent TB in South Africa may imperil millions. The New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Diana Sonntag .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sonntag, D. (2010). Profiling the Provision Status of Health-Promoting Public Goods Against AIDS. In: AIDS and Aid. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2419-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics