Skip to main content

Labor Market Effects of Services Offshoring: Empirical Evidence

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Services Offshoring and its Impact on the Labor Market

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

This fifth chapter constitutes the major contribution of this work. It comprises a collection of three empirical studies, which estimate the effects of services offshoring on productivity (Sect. 5.1), labor demand (Sect. 5.2), and the relative demand for less-skilled labor (Sect. 5.3) in German manufacturing. The formulation of the hypotheses is based on the underlying theoretical models. Our econometric estimations use both unrevised (1991–2000) and revised (1995–2004) input–output data. We use two different estimation methods for all of our studies, which increases the reliability of our estimation results. Services offshoring had a positive effect on total factor productivity and labor productivity in German manufacturing, while it affected labor demand negatively. Both effects were stronger between 1995 and 2004. The overall results suggest that labor demand decreased, because labor-reducing productivity and substitution effects dominated labor-augmenting scale effects from services offshoring. Moreover, services offshoring significantly reduced the relative demand for less-skilled labor from 1991 to 2000. Interestingly, the results for 1995 to 2004 indicate a relative demand shift away from high-skilled labor, mitigating the declining wage share of less-skilled labor.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Due to the homogeneity assumption multiplying the inputs with a constant λ (λ = 2, 3, …) augments production by λ z where z is constant and positive: \({\lambda ^z Y = F(\lambda L,\lambda K,\lambda S,\lambda M,\lambda T)}\).

  2. 2.

    Producer price indices are available at several aggregation levels (28, 107 and 225 sectors). Since some producer prices at the required input–output aggregation level were not available, we used producer prices of more disaggregated sectors (within the same industry) as a proxy, because similar price trends can be expected there. The same procedure was also applied in a few cases where the time series was incomplete.

  3. 3.

    Besides Hijzen et al. (2005), other authors, e.g., Falk and Koebel (2002), Strauss-Kahn (2003) or Geishecker (2006), also used net capital stocks when measuring labor demand equations, whereas the OECD (2007) study uses the gross fixed capital formation due to data limitations. Other studies do not offer further information on the capital used.

  4. 4.

    For instance, no sectoral data are available for “food products” and “beverages,” but only for the aggregated sector “food products and beverages”. Since a similar productivity in both sectors can be assumed, we multiplied the net capital stock of the aggregated sector with the respective individual output shares to obtain the net capital stock for each sector. This procedure was done in the following eight sectors, where the net capital stock data of the German national accounts (VGR) have aggregated levels: 1–2, 8–9, 10–11, 15–16, 17–18, 19–21, 32–33, and 35–36.

  5. 5.

    We dropped the identified outliers “pharmaceuticals” and “office, accounting and computer machinery” due to extremely high services offshoring intensities, which leads to a total of 34 manufacturing sectors.

  6. 6.

    Subdividing capital into capital spendings on equipment and buildings did not lead to significant results in the previous estimations.

  7. 7.

    We dropped the identified outliers “pharmaceuticals”, due to extremely high services offshoring intensities, and “tobacco”, due to very low output figures combined with a high OSS, which leads to a total of 33 manufacturing sectors.

  8. 8.

    Capital spending on equipment and buildings is aggregated, since disaggregation yields no significant results for both variables.

  9. 9.

    According to Shephard's Lemma (1953) factor demand is determined by the first partial derivative of the cost function with respect to the corresponding factor price, regardless of the kind of production function.

  10. 10.

    Note that a * as a superscript in this section refers to the equilibrium amount.

  11. 11.

    Thus, for instance, wage data are only available for the aggregated sector “food products and beverages”. The wages of the aggregated sector are weighted with the respective output shares of the individual sectors “food products” and “beverages” in order to achieve disaggregated sectoral wages. This procedure was done eight times in the following sectors: 1–2, 8–9, 10–11, 15–16, 17–18, 19–21, 32–33, and 35–36.

  12. 12.

    As in Sect. 5.1.2, the two outliers “pharmaceuticals” and “office, accounting and computer machinery” are dropped due to extremely high services offshoring intensities.

  13. 13.

    The outlier “pharmaceuticals” is excluded from the cross-section due to its extremely high services offshoring intensities, which leads to a total of 34 manufacturing sectors.

  14. 14.

    According to Shephard's Lemma (1953), the factor demand X j * is determined by the first partial derivative of the cost function with respect to the corresponding factor price P j , regardless of the kind of production function. Note that a * as a superscript in this section refers to the equilibrium amount.

  15. 15.

    The translog cost function in the empirical work on trade and the demand for heterogeneous labor was first introduced by Berman et al. (1994) and applied by e.g., Feenstra and Hanson (1996), Geishecker (2002, 2006), Strauss-Kahn (2003), Hijzen et al. (2005), and Ekholm and Hakkala (2006).

  16. 16.

    We dropped the subscripts LS in the coefficients of (5.29).

  17. 17.

    The following sectors have been aggregated: 1-2, 8-9, 13-14, 15-16, 17-18, 19-21, and 35-36.

  18. 18.

    The two outliers “office, accounting and computer machinery” and chemicals (including pharmaceuticals) are dropped due to their high services offshoring intensities, leading to a total of 26 manufacturing sectors.

  19. 19.

    The outlier “pharmaceuticals” is excluded due to extremely high services offshoring intensities, which leads to a total of 33 manufacturing sectors.

References

  • Amiti M, Wei S-J (2005) Fear of service outsourcing: is it justified? Econ Policy 20(42):308-347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Wei S-J (2006) Service offshoring, productivity and employment: evidence from the US. CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 5475, February 2006

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman E, Bound J, Griliches Z (1994) Changes in the demand for skilled labor within U.S. manufacturing: evidence from the annual survey of manufacturers. Q J Econ 109(2):367-397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown RS, Christensen LR (1981) Estimating elasticities of substitution in a model of partial static equilibrium: an application to U.S. agriculture, 1947-1974. In Berndt ER, Field BC (eds) Modeling and measuring natural resource substitution. MIT, Cambridge, MA, pp 209-229

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekholm K, Hakkala K (2006) The effect of offshoring on labour demand: evidence from Sweden. CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 5648, April 2006

    Google Scholar 

  • Falk M, Koebel BM (2002) Outsourcing, imports and labour demand. Scand J Econ 104(4): 567-586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrel D (2004) Can Germany win from offshoring. July 2004. McKinsey Global Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (1996) Globalization, outsourcing and wage inequality. Am Econ Rev 86(2):240-245

    Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I (2002) Outsourcing and the demand for low-skilled labour in german manufacturing: new evidence. DIW Discussion Paper, No. 313, November 2002

    Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I (2006) Does outsourcing to central and eastern europe really threaten manual workers' jobs in Germany? World Econ 29(5):559-583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh D (1993) Labor demand. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen A, Görg H, Hine RC (2005) International outsourcing and the skill structure of labour demand in the United Kingdom. Econ J 115(506):860-878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houseman S (2006) Outsourcing, offshoring, and productivity measurement in U.S. Manufacturing. Upjohn Institute Staff Working Paper, No. 06-130, June 2006

    Google Scholar 

  • McKinsey Global Institute (2005) How offshoring of services could benefit France. June 2005, McKinsey Global Institute

    Google Scholar 

  • Milberg W, Schöller D (2008) Globalization, offshoring and economic insecurity in industrialized countries. World Economic and Social Survey 2008 Background Paper. Department of Economic and Social Affairs, United Nations, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Milberg W, v Arnim R, Mahoney M, Schneider M (2007) Dynamic gains from U.S. services offshoring: a critical view. In: Paus E (ed) Global capitalism unbound: winners and losers from offshore outsourcing. Palgrave Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2007) Offshoring and employment: trends and impact. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Roling J (1999) Bedeuten deutsche Direktinvestitionen im Ausland einen Export' deutscher Arbeitsplätze? Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftspolitik 48(2):147-167

    Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW (1953) Cost and Production Functions. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Stockhammer E (2004) Financialisation and the slowdown of accumulation. Camb J Econ 28(5):719-741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strauss-Kahn V (2003) The role of globalization in the within-industry shift away from unskilled workers in France. NBER Working Paper, No. 9716, May 2003

    Google Scholar 

  • Tüselmann H-J (1998) Deutsche Auslandsinvestitionen in den neunziger Jahren: Abwanderung der deutschen Industrie und Abbau von Arbeitsplätzen? WSI Mitteilungen 5:292-303

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1962) Production functions with constant elasticity of substitution. Rev Econ Stud 29(4):291-299

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Deborah Winkler .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Physica-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Winkler, D. (2009). Labor Market Effects of Services Offshoring: Empirical Evidence. In: Services Offshoring and its Impact on the Labor Market. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2199-4_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics