Skip to main content

Employment Effects of Innovation Activities

  • Chapter
Innovation and Firm Performance

Part of the book series: ZEW Economic Studies ((ZEW,volume 38))

  • 715 Accesses

Abstract

The question of how technological progress affects the employment situation is an old one and has long been the focus of theoretical and empirical industrial organisation research as well as lively public discussions.33 The controversial debates on this issue mainly result from the fact that, from a theoretical point of view, different channels exist through which innovations can destroy existing jobs (displacement effects) but that there are also several mechanisms through which innovations may create new jobs (compensation effects). In addition, product and process innovations influence employment via different channels. The overall impact depends on a number of firm-, sector- as well as country-specific factors.

This chapter is largely based on Peters (2004). The model in section 3.4.1 and the international comparison in section 3.6 largely draws on a joint paper with Rupert Harrison, Jordi Jaumandreu, and Jacques Mairesse, see Harrison et al. (2005).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. For a historical overview, see Petit (1995) or Freeman and Soete (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  2. Closely related to the aspect of the shift in the labour demand from low-to high-skilled personnel is the increasing inequality of the relative wages across skill groups (see, e.g., Fitzenberger, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Traditionally, patents have been used as an indicator to measure innovation output. However, patent-based indicators have been heavily criticised as being a poor measure of innovative outcome (see Griliches, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  4. The result of Zimmermann (1991) is an exception.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Hall, Lotti, and Mairesse (2006) modified the model by specifying two relationships between the observed price from the statistical office and firm-level prices for old and new products.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See figures on the labour force development in Fachserie 1, Reihe 4.2.1 published by Statistisches Bundesamt (a) or Peters (2003). Moreover, one can observe an employment shift within the manufacturing as well as service sector to more knowledge-intensive branches; see Pfeiffer and Falk (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  7. The DWH test is based on an artificial regression by including the predicted value of the endogenous right-hand-side variable (as a function of all exogenous variables) in a regression of the original model and applying an F test for significance of the additional regressor (see Davidson and MacKinnon, 1993). Using, for instance, the instruments proposed in regression (2) in Tables 3.7 and 3.8, the DWH statistic was 44.74 (p-value: 0.000) in manufacturing and 8.60 (0.003) in services; using the preferred instruments of regression (6), the corresponding figures were 4.46 (0.035) and 7.14 (0.008).

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Hahn and Hausman (2002: 166–169) for the calculation of the test statistic.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Hahn and Hausman (2002) suggest a sequential test procedure. If the null hypothesis of this test has been rejected, a similar specification test based on second-order unbiased Nagar-estimators should be carried out. If the second test has not led to a rejection of the null hypothesis, the limited-information maximum likelihood (LIML) estimator as the optimal combination of Nagar-estimators should be applied. If the second test has likewise failed, none of these estimators should be used at all.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Using CIS 2 data covering the period 1994–1996, Falk (1999) showed that only market novelties have stimulated the expected labour demand. The expected employment change was an ordinal variable in the data set which required a different estimation method (ordered probit model). Furthermore, he used dummy variables for both kinds of product innovations. Replacing the continuous variables in eq. (3.16) with their dummy counterparts, however, did not alter the qualitative results.

    Google Scholar 

  11. König, Licht, and Buscher (1995) found a significant positive effect of process innovations for the boom period 1990–1992 while Blechinger and Pfeiffer (1999) reported a significant negative effect for the recession period 1993–1995.

    Google Scholar 

  12. According to Gibrat’s law, firms grow (in terms of employment or sales) proportionally and independently of their size, see Gibrat (1934). In contrast to that, Jovanovic (1982), for instance, stressed the importance of managerial efficiency and learning by doing and developed a model in which surviving young and small firms grow faster than older and larger ones.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2008). Employment Effects of Innovation Activities. In: Innovation and Firm Performance. ZEW Economic Studies, vol 38. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2026-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics