Skip to main content

China’s reform process, stock market development, and testable hypotheses

  • Chapter
Corporate Control and Enterprise Reform in China

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

Milton Friedman states in the 2002 preface of his classic “Capitalism and Freedom” that “there is no doubt that the residents of China are freer and more prosperous than they were under Mao — freer in every dimension except the political”.16 This statement rests on the fact that China is uniformly ruled by the Communist Party of China (CPC). Nevertheless, to fully understand the factors that shape economic policy-making in China, the incentives and constraints among the interest groups within China’s political structure need to be considered. In general, opposition has taken place within a three-level state structure: The senior leadership, central government leaders and local government leaders.17

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Friedman (2002, p. ix).

    Google Scholar 

  2. For details regarding the organizational structure of the CPC, see Shambaugh (2000, pp. 168–173) and regarding the structure of power within the CPC, see Lieberthal and Oksenberg (1990, pp. 135–168).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Cited after Prasad (2004, p. 2).

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Yusuf et al. (2006, p. 116).

    Google Scholar 

  5. The following section on the current structure of the Chinese economy is derived from an OECD survey of China’s business sector and a World Bank survey on China’s ownership transformation. See OECD (2005a, pp. 81 and 135) and Garnaut et al. (2005, pp. 7–8).

    Google Scholar 

  6. Value added is defined as gross output minus intermediate consumption and equals the sum of employee compensation, net operating surplus and depreciation of capital assets. Firms are separated by the type of controlling shareholder. Private sector includes both domestic and overseas private firms and investment. The public sector includes state controlled (directly or indirectly) and collectively controlled enterprises. The non-farm business sector excludes agriculture, government and non-profit service sectors. It was equivalent to 76 per cent of GDP in 1998 and 79 per cent in 2003. See OECD (2005a, pp. 81 and 135).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Total number of national enterprises covers all state-owned industrial enterprises and enterprises with annual sales of over RMB5million. Return on assets is calculated as operating surplus divided by fixed assets plus inventories. Unless stated otherwise, reported data is for October 2004. See Garnaut et al. (2005, p. 7).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Total factor productivity of directly controlled state firms is less than half that of privately controlled firms based on OECD (2005a, pp. 97–98) estimates using comprehensive industrial micro data.

    Google Scholar 

  9. This section is mostly based on two OECD surveys on domestic policy challenges and enterprise governance in China. See OECD (2002, pp. 12–18) and OECD (2005b, pp. 309 and 312–13). Naughton (1995) provides a detailed discussion on China’s earlier enterprise reforms from a historic perspective.

    Google Scholar 

  10. In particular, the “contract responsibility system” implemented performance contracts between the government and firm management. Shirley and Xu (2001) analyse this institutional arrangement.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Cited after Tenev et al. (2002, p. 28).

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Garnaut et al. (2005, pp. 2–7) for a detailed discussion of the numerous ways that Chinese firms have been exited and restructured.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Tenev et al. (2002, p. 20); Garnaut et al. (2005, p. 33); OECD (2005a, p. 97) report that “87 per cent of the decline in the number of state held industrial firms in the period 1998–2003 came from the prefecture and county level”.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Several studies relate the incentives given to local officials to different economic factors, such as fiscal decentralization, emergence of local government ownership, or interregional competition in product markets; see Qian and Weingast (1997), Che and Qian (1998), and Li, Li, and Zhang (2000) respectively.

    Google Scholar 

  15. The following section is based on Liu, Sun, and Woo (2006, pp. 2020–2026).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Li and Zhou (2005, p. 1760) analyze turnover data of top provincial leaders between 1979 and 1995 and find that the likelihood of promotion of provincial leaders increases with their economic performance.

    Google Scholar 

  17. The second half of the 1990s witnessed considerable centralization and commercialization of the banking system. Reforms imposed strict targets on China’s four state-owned banks to control their non-performing loans. Coupled with the ongoing banking reform is the largely completed fiscal reform, which has institutionalized the division of tax revenues between the central and local governments. For details on the central-local government fiscal relations and the banking reform see OECD (2002, pp. 53–58).

    Google Scholar 

  18. See Liu, Sun, and Woo (2006, pp. 2022–2023).

    Google Scholar 

  19. The SASAC is under direct authority of the State Council. The priorities for action by the SASAC include the creation and enhancement of the role of boards in SOE, the establishment of a well structured and transparent board nomination process and the restriction of irregular behavior by the state as a controlling shareholder. For a detailed definition of its duties refer to Ling (2004, p. 3) and Chen (2004, p. 2).

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Sun and Tong (2003, p. 187).

    Google Scholar 

  21. In particular, excess labour is generated in rural areas by productivity gains in the agricultural sector and in urban areas by the downsizing of SOE; see OECD (2002, p. 24) for details.

    Google Scholar 

  22. The inter-provincial divergence of GDP per capita has risen dramatically. Most central and western provinces have lost substantially in comparison to 1980. In Gansu province, for instance, per capita income fell from 84% of national average in 1980 to 56% in 1999. See Taube and Ögütcü (2002, p. 3).

    Google Scholar 

  23. Cited after Green (2004, p. 7).

    Google Scholar 

  24. The description of the typical listing process is based on Green and Liu (2005, pp. 113–118).

    Google Scholar 

  25. A-shares are the most actively traded shares in China; see Shirai (2004, p. 1470) for details.

    Google Scholar 

  26. B-shares are held by foreign individuals and institutions and since March 2001 by domestic individuals in China. H-and N-shares refer to listings in Hong Kong and New York, respectively. Other overseas shares include “red chips”. This term refers to Hong Kong registered holding companies into which Chinese assets have been injected; see Wang, Xu, and Zhu (2004, pp. 470–474). See Appendix A.1: List of share categories of China’s stock market, p. 105.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See Groenewold et al. (2005, p. 5).

    Google Scholar 

  28. Since secondary market P/E multiples were commonly higher, share prices would usually rocket on the first trading day. This created huge incentives for the take-up of IPOs and thus fulfilled the governments need to create sufficient IPO demand. See Green (2003, pp. 162–163).

    Google Scholar 

  29. See Pistor and Xu (2005b, p. 7).

    Google Scholar 

  30. These firms are usually also required to issue non-tradable shares to their founding owners. The average float of their total equity at year-end 2002 was 31 per cent; see Green (2003, p. 152).

    Google Scholar 

  31. State-controlled legal entities include publicly listed firms, SOE, unlisted firms and academic institutions. Liu and Sun (2005, p. 48) apply the concept of ultimate control of La Porta et al. (1999, pp. 476–477) to the context of Chinesestyle stock pyramids.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See Jones et al. (1999, p. 230).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Perotti (1995, pp. 855–856) argues that initial sales are likely to be smaller so that the governments could signal to investors that policy reversals are unlikely because the government will bear redistribution costs associated with regulatory interference.

    Google Scholar 

  34. See Huang and Xu (2005, p. 12).

    Google Scholar 

  35. See Green (2003, p. 196).

    Google Scholar 

  36. After agreement over the conversion price has been reached, a 12 month lockup period is established for the holders of tradable shares. In the two years after expiration of the lock-up, a holder of non-tradable shares with more than 5% of the total issued share capital of the listed company is further prohibited from trading on the stock exchange more than 5% (10%) of the company’s total share capital within 12 (24) months. See CSRC (2005) for further details.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Inoue (2005, pp. 45–53).

    Google Scholar 

  38. Chen and Shih (2002, pp. 62–68) and Green (2004, pp. 137–157) provide extensive discussion on the rise of the CSRC.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Wedeman (1999, pp. 118–119) provides a review of the different channels used by local leaders to defect from central government guidelines.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Huang (1996, p. 656) discusses the administrative control structure among central and local leaders.

    Google Scholar 

  41. For an extensive summary of the legal framework see OECD (2002, pp. 49–53).

    Google Scholar 

  42. See Wilson and Tao (2006, p. 30).

    Google Scholar 

  43. See Walter et al. (2003, p. 67).

    Google Scholar 

  44. This section is primarily based on Green and Liu (2005, pp. 135–137) and Green (2004, pp. 66–74)

    Google Scholar 

  45. According to OECD (2005b, p. 316) this framework is oriented towards protecting investors from ‚fake ‘acquisitions since some deals are aimed at manipulating market prices.

    Google Scholar 

  46. The CSRC’s M&A regulations include a framework for tender offers. According to Green (2004, p. 70) these rules were largely redundant. There were few incentives for launching a market-based takeover since the majority shareholder controlled a much larger stake than could be accumulated on the market.

    Google Scholar 

  47. This section is based on Liu (2006, pp. 418–419). The author provides a first review of the evolving research on corporate governance in China.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Wong, Opper, and Hu (2004, pp. 33 and 40) report that Chinese Communist Party committees retain considerable decision-making power in listed firms over personnel decisions. Furthermore, 56% of listed firms retain ties with the government and ministries.

    Google Scholar 

  49. This report was issued by the CSRC and the State Economic and Trade Commission (SETC); see OECD (2005b, p. 308).

    Google Scholar 

  50. For general surveys of corporate governance see Denis and McConnell (2003) and Shleifer and Vishney (1997). For a review of corporate governance in Asia see Claessens and Fan (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  51. See Kose and Senbet (1998, p. 379).

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Fan et al. (2007, pp. 20–24).

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Bai et al. (2004, p. 613).

    Google Scholar 

  54. According to the guidelines, an individual must meet the following conditions to be considered independent. First, neither the individual nor his or her relatives may work for the listed firm or its subsidiaries. Second, the individual may not directly or indirectly own more than 1 per cent of the listed firm. Third, neither the individual nor his or her relatives may be among the largest 10 shareholders of the listed firm. Fourth, neither the individual nor his or her relatives may work for a company that owns more than 5 per cent of the stock of the listed firm. Fifth, neither the individual nor his or her relatives may work for one of the largest 5 shareholder companies; see World Bank (2002, pp. 83–99).

    Google Scholar 

  55. Kato and Long (2006, pp. 806 and 811).

    Google Scholar 

  56. Interestingly, they find that internationally well-reputed audit firms do not deter corporate fraud any more than other auditors. See Chen et al. (2006, pp. 441 and 445).

    Google Scholar 

  57. Bai et al. (2004, p. 608) report average managerial holdings of only 0.1 per cent.

    Google Scholar 

  58. See Shleifer and Vishny (1994, p. 996) and Boycko et al. (1996, p. 317).

    Google Scholar 

  59. Chang and Wong (2004, p. 619) and Xu, Zhu, and Lin (2005, p. 2) call the incentive problems of managers ‘agency costs’ and the incentive problems of shareholders ‘expropriation’.

    Google Scholar 

  60. However, politicians often maintained formal authority over key personnel and investment decisions and, in particular, over labour decisions; see Xu, Zhu, and Lin (2005, p. 5).

    Google Scholar 

  61. See Chang and Wong (2004, p. 618).

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Xu and Wang (1999, p. 88).

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Tian (2001, pp. 29–30).

    Google Scholar 

  64. See Sun et al. (2002, p. 23).

    Google Scholar 

  65. See e.g. Xu and Wang (1999, p. 92); Wei et al. (2005, p. 98); Sun et al. (2002, p. 22).

    Google Scholar 

  66. See Liu and Sun (2005, p. 52).

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Chang et al. (2004, pp. 619 and 632).

    Google Scholar 

  68. See Xu et al. (2005, pp. 18 and 22).

    Google Scholar 

  69. See Cheung et al. (2005, pp. 25 and 30).

    Google Scholar 

  70. See Jensen (1993, pp. 850–852).

    Google Scholar 

  71. See Jensen and Ruback (1983) for the US and Franks and Mayer (1995) for the UK.

    Google Scholar 

  72. See e.g. Fan et al. (2007, p. 4), Chen et al. (2006, p. 432); Kato and Long (2006, p. 799).

    Google Scholar 

  73. See Cai and Chen (2004, p. 79).

    Google Scholar 

  74. See Chen et al. (2007, p. 20).

    Google Scholar 

  75. See La Porta et al. (1998, p. 1151).

    Google Scholar 

  76. See OECD (2005b, p. 318).

    Google Scholar 

  77. A company is placed in ST category if (1) it has negative net profits for two consecutive fiscal years; (2) the shareholder’ equity is lower than the registered capital; (3) a firm’s operations have been stopped; or (4) if the firm is involved in a damaging lawsuit or arbitration. If a firm is unable to turn around within a certain period, it will be further downgraded to PT and may face de-listing; See Bai et al. (2002, pp. 7–9).

    Google Scholar 

  78. See Green (2003, pp. 188–9).

    Google Scholar 

  79. See Pistor and Xu (2005a, pp. 190–196 and 204).

    Google Scholar 

  80. See Allen (2005, p. 174)

    Google Scholar 

  81. Allen, Qian, Qian (2005, p. 81) report that around 30 per cent of listed firms’ funding comes from bank loans, and that this ratio has been very stable despite the fast growth of the stock markets. See Allen et al. (2005, pp. 76–78 and 80–83) for details of the banking reform and the importance of the banking system in financing the domestic economy.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Jensen (1988, p. 23) views the market for corporate control as a major component of the managerial labour market in which alternative management teams compete for the right to manage corporate resources. Scharfstein (1988, p. 185) interpretes the takeover mechanism as an indirect means for shareholders to renegotiate their contract with management.

    Google Scholar 

  83. See e.g. Bethel et al. (1998, p. 624) for the US and Holmstrom and Kaplan (2001) for a review of the US literature; Köke (2004, p. 68) provides empirical evidence for Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  84. See La Porta et al. (1999, p. 498).

    Google Scholar 

  85. See Shleifer and Vishny (1986, p. 464).

    Google Scholar 

  86. See Köke (2004, p. 75).

    Google Scholar 

  87. Shleifer and Vishny (1997, p. 757).

    Google Scholar 

  88. See Edin (2003, p. 39).

    Google Scholar 

  89. Liu et al. (2006, p. 2029) suggest the average compensation cost per worker as a measure of the importance of labour in the Chinese privatization process. Such data, however, was not available.

    Google Scholar 

  90. Jensen (1986, p. 328) argues that takeovers occur in response to breakdowns of internal control processes in firms and that management is likely to invest free cash flow in inefficient projects of monitoring is not strict enough. Bringing the firm back on track requires to revert these investments through asset sales or lay-offs.

    Google Scholar 

  91. This includes essentially price liberalizations and the removal of entry barriers; see Guo and Yao (2005, p. 216).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2008). China’s reform process, stock market development, and testable hypotheses. In: Corporate Control and Enterprise Reform in China. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2020-1_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics