Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

This chapter gives an in-depth overview of the Indian banking sector and its structural setting. The focus is on the development of the sector since 1947, with special emphasis on the reforms that have taken place since 1991. Furthermore, it examines the structural setting of the Indian banking sector and its political, economic and institutional environment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See Cygnus Economic & Business Research (2004), p. 5; ICRA (2004), p. 4;Reddy (2002b), p. 337.

    Google Scholar 

  2. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 110f.; Shirai (2002c), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 3f.; Cygnus Economic & Business Research (2004), p. 5; Hanson (2001b), p. 261; Kumbhakar and Sarkar (2003), p. 406f.; Reddy (2002b), p. 337.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See ICRA (2004), p. 5; Reddy (2002b), p. 338; Shirai (2002c), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  5. The launch of the first Indian five-year plan was in 1951. The plans provided a general framework for the allocation of capital and lined out key policies such as “import substitution”, but were not as extensive as the five-year plans in the Soviet Union or in China. See Jalan (2005), p. 46f.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Arun and Turner (2002a), p. 184; Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 4; Hanson (2001a), p. 2; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 111; Kumbhakar and Sarkar (2003), p. 407; Reddy (2002b), p. 338.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Desai (1999), p. 14.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Deolalkar (1999), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  9. See Arun and Turner (2002a), p. 184; Hanson (2001a), p. 2f.; Kumbhakar and Sarkar (2003), p. 407.

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 5; Shirai (2002c), p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See Panagariya (2004), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Mukherji (2002), p. 39.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Desai (1999), p. 20; Oschinski (2003), p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  14. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 14f; Oschinski (2003), p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  15. See Desai (1999), p. 24; Oschinski (2003), p. 7; Singh (2005), p. 4f.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See Halbach and Helmschrott (1994), p. 34; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 14. In fact, before the economy was opened up, other policy measures such as increasing restrictions or restraining growth were tried unsuccessfully to stabilize the economy. See Desai (1999), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Government of India (1991), p. 3f.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Joshi and Little (1997), p. 111.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 111. In addition to their weak financial performance, the banks also provided a very low quality of service despite a large personnel overhang. See Halbach and Helmschrott (1994), p. 53; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 112.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Demetriades and Luintel (1997), p. 314f.; Shirai (2002c), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Arun and Turner (2002a), p. 183; Guha-Khasnobis and Bhaduri (2000), p. 335f.; Hanson (2001a), p. 5; Mohan (2004), p. 852; Shirai (2002c), p. 7; Werner (1999), p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See Ahluwalia (2002), p. 81.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Reservable Liabilities are net demand and time liabilities less all liabilities exempted from statutory reserve requirements. See Shirai (2002c), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Regional Rural Banks are not required to deposit the CRR. See Shirai (2002c), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See Ghose (2000), p. 199; Government of India (1991), p. 26f.; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 10; Shirai (2002c), p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  26. See Ghose (2000), p. 199; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 10; Shirai (2002c), p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  27. See Government of India (1991), p. 25; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 10; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 3; Shirai (2002c), p. 12. The interest-rate environment contributed to the increased demand for government securities, since banks could profit from falling interest rates. See Sy (2005), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Demetriades and Luintel (1997), p. 320; Reserve Bank of India “Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India”, various issues. The 25% SLR ratio was between 1993 and 1997 applied to increases over deposits on a base date. See Hanson (2001a), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See Kamesam (2002), p. 379; Reddy (2002a), p. 364; Reserve Bank of India (2003), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Bhattacharya and Patel (2004), p. 17.

    Google Scholar 

  31. See Ganesan (2003), p. 14; Government of India (1991), p. 27; Raje (2000), p. 28; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 16; Shirai (2002c), p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See Ganesan (2003), p. 14; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 130. Hanson (2001b) reports that in 1988 the overview of the various lending rates covered ten pages. See Hanson (2001b), p. 246.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See Government of India (1991), p. 29 and p. 44.

    Google Scholar 

  34. See Hanson (2001a), p. 8; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 16; Shirai (2002c), p. 18. Priority sector lending requirements for foreign banks stand at the current level of 32% since 1993. The sub-targets for foreign and domestic banks are different as well. Foreign banks for example have a 10% target for the export sector, which is not the case for domestic banks. See Shirai (2002c), p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See Arun and Turner (2002b), p. 437; Government of India (1991), p. 46; Sen and Vaidya (1997), p. 75; Singh (2005), p. 18; Varma (2002), p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Arun and Turner (2002b), p. 437; Hanson (2001a), p. 8; Hanson (2001b), p. 250f.; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 15; Shirai (2002c), p. 13. An early attempt to liberalize loan rates actually started in 1988 by turning the maximum rate on non-directed credit into a minimum rate. See Hanson (2001a), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Mohan (2006b), p. 2; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 14; Shirai (2002c), p. 13f.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Reserve Bank of India (2005a); Shirai (2002c), p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  39. See Hawkins and Mihaljek (2001), p. 3; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Deolalkar (1999), p. 60; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 148; Kamesam (2002), p. 380; Reddy (2002b), p. 340.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See Reserve Bank of India (2005b), p. 1; Shirai (2002c), p. 19f. The ceiling on individual shareholding was increased to 10% after the amendment of the Banking Regulation Act in 1994. See Shirai (2002c), p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See Arun and Turner (2002b) p. 439; Hanson (2001a), p. 6; ICRA (2004), p. 23; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), pp. 231–233; Shirai (2002c), p. 20.

    Google Scholar 

  43. See Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 2; Koch (1998), p. 76f.; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 167.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Gupta and Jayakar (2005), p. 60; Indian Banks’ Association (2003), p. 19; Reserve Bank of India (2005b), p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See Leeladhar (2006), p. 75; Reserve Bank of India (2004c), p. 1; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 101.

    Google Scholar 

  46. See Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 3; Shirai (2002c), p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  47. See Shirai (2002c), p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  48. The average sum of deposits and credit in rural branches stood at about Rs 870,000 (approximately EUR 14,900 based on an exchange rate of 58.54 Rs/EUR as of June 30th 2006) in 2004, which is likely to be insufficient to cover costs. In comparison, the volume of deposits and credit was 4.7 times higher in urban branches and about 15 times higher in metropolitan branches. Calculations based on Reserve Bank of India (2004a), p. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  49. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 115; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 24.

    Google Scholar 

  50. See Government of India (1991) pp. 51–59.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See Chipalkatti and Rishi (2003), p. 2f.; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 24; Shirai (2002c), p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 117; Shirai (2002c), p. 21f. The 8% capital adequacy ratio is based on risk-weighted assets. At least half of the capital has to be tier 1 capital (equity and disclosed reserves). Tier 2 capital includes among others hybrid debt capital instruments. The risk-adjusted assets include both on-and off-balance sheet items and receive risk weights of 0%, 20%, 50% and 100%. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (1997), p. 23f.; Santos (2000), p. 17.

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Reserve Bank of India (2000), p. 5. The Narasimham Committee had suggested to increase the minimum capital to risk assets ratio from 8% to 10% to account for the increased off-balance sheet exposure of banks. See Government of India (1998), p. 22.

    Google Scholar 

  54. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 95. The rating agency Fitch estimates that the effective level of NPLs in India could be twice as high as reported due to less stringent classification norms. See Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  55. See ICRA (2004), p. 22f.; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 117; Shirai (2002c), p. 22. Loans are classified as substandard if they have been non-performing for up to two years and require a 10% provision. If the loan has been non-performing for more than two years, it is classified as doubtful and a provision of between 20–50% is made. To be classified as a loss, a loan has to be certified as a loss by an external auditor. In this event a 100% provision for the loan is made. See ICRA (2004), p. 22f.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See Madgavkar, Puri and Sengupta (2001), p. 114.

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Indian Banks’ Association (2003), p. 29; Joshi and Little (1997), p. 117f; Reddy (2002a), p. 364; Reddy (2002b), p. 340; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 24f.; Singh (2005), p. 23.

    Google Scholar 

  58. See Shirai (2002c), p. 23. The acronym CAMEL stands for Capital adequacy, Asset quality, Management soundness, Earnings and profitability, and Liquidity. Commonly, the sensitivity to market risk is included as a sixth component of the framework. See International Monetary Fund (2000a), pp. 4–9 for a detailed description of the elements of the framework.

    Google Scholar 

  59. See Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), p. 28; Mukherji (2002), p. 40. For a comprehensive overview of applicable prudential norms in the Indian banking sector see Reserve Bank of India (2004b), pp. 206–210.

    Google Scholar 

  60. See Kamesam (2002), p. 377; Reddy (2002a), p. 358.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See Government of India (1991), p. 67.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Shirai (2002c), p. 26.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Deolalkar (1999), p. 66f.

    Google Scholar 

  64. See Reddy (2002a), p. 359; Reserve Bank of India (1999), section 5.1; Reserve Bank of India (2001b), p. 26. Table 13 in the appendix provides an overview of the recapitalization amounts.

    Google Scholar 

  65. See Muniappan (2002), p. 2f.; Reserve Bank of India “Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India”, various issues. Note: (1) values for 1992–1996 include only PSBs; (2) net NPLs are gross NPLs less provisions made for nonperforming loans.

    Google Scholar 

  66. See Reserve Bank of India (2001b), p. 24.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Mukherji (2002), p. 40; Reserve Bank of India (1999), sections 5.2 and 5.4.

    Google Scholar 

  68. See Stiglitz and Bhattacharya (1999), p. 114.

    Google Scholar 

  69. See Ahluwalia (2002), p. 82; Madgavkar, Puri and Sengupta (2001), p. 114; Reserve Bank of India (2001a), p. 11. Equally important is that adequate bankruptcy laws can reduce incentives for deceptive practices by borrowers. Consequently, bankruptcy laws are not only important to clean up the bad loans of the past, but also to prevent them in the future. See Buiter, Lago and Rey (1999), p. 146.

    Google Scholar 

  70. See Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 35; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 37; Shirai (2002c), p. 25.

    Google Scholar 

  71. See Center for the Advanced Study of India (2004), p. 33; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 35.

    Google Scholar 

  72. See Arun and Turner (2002b), pp. 436–442; Bhide, Prasad and Ghosh (2001), pp. 7–13; Economist Intelligence Unit (2005), p. 10; Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 2; Hanson (2001a), p. 8; ICRA (2004), p. 23; Saez and Yang (2001), p. 80; Shirai (2002a), pp. 54–56; Shirai (2002c), p. 26. An overview of the government holdings in state-owned banks can be found in Table 14 in the appendix.

    Google Scholar 

  73. See Ahluwalia (2002), p. 82; ICRA (2004), p. 23f.

    Google Scholar 

  74. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c).

    Google Scholar 

  75. See Reserve Bank of India Act 42 (6).

    Google Scholar 

  76. See Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  77. See Deolalkar (1999), p. 61.

    Google Scholar 

  78. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c).

    Google Scholar 

  79. See Deolalkar (1999), pp. 64–66.

    Google Scholar 

  80. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 108.

    Google Scholar 

  81. See Basu and Srivastava (2005), p. 138f. and p. 150; Morduch (2000), p. 617; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 129f.; Swain (2002), p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  82. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 139.

    Google Scholar 

  83. See Deolalkar (1999), p. 62f.; Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 140; Sunder Ram (2001), p. 56.

    Google Scholar 

  84. See Basu (2005), p. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  85. See Reserve Bank of India (2005c), p. 139 and pp. 149–152.

    Google Scholar 

  86. See Basu (2005), p. 7; Reserve Bank of India (2004b), p. 146.

    Google Scholar 

  87. See Rao (2002), p. 4f.

    Google Scholar 

  88. See Mukherji (2002), p. 59; Singh (2003), p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  89. See Echeverri-Gent (2001), p. 3; Jalan (2005), p. 89.

    Google Scholar 

  90. See Echeverri-Gent (2001), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  91. See Datta-Chaudhuri (1990), p. 29f.; Oschinski (2003), pp. 3–5.

    Google Scholar 

  92. See Datta-Chaudhuri (1990), p. 29; Mukherji (2002), p. 31.

    Google Scholar 

  93. See Rodrik and Subramanian (2004), p. 4; Swamy (2005a), p. 81. See Kohli (2006a) and Kohli (2006b) for a detailed discussion of the political-economy factors leading to India’s growth acceleration.

    Google Scholar 

  94. Author’s calculation based on International Monetary Fund (2006b).

    Google Scholar 

  95. See Acharya (2002), p. 11; Government of India (2006); Pandit (2005), p. 135f.

    Google Scholar 

  96. See Deutsche Bank Research (2006), p. 2; Echeverri-Gent (2001), p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  97. See Government of India (2006); International Monetary Fund (2006b).

    Google Scholar 

  98. See Basu and Srivastava (2005), p. 146; Mukherji (2006), p. 6; Pandit (2005), p. 136.

    Google Scholar 

  99. See Joshi and Little (1997), p. 166f.; Kohli (2001), p. 3; Mohan (2006b), p. 4f.

    Google Scholar 

  100. See Kohli (2001), p. 7 and p. 11; Mohan (2006b), p. 6f.

    Google Scholar 

  101. See Cygnus Economic & Business Research (2004), p. 5; Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  102. See Fitch Ratings (2003), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  103. See Desai (1999), p. 36; ICRA (2004), p. 23.

    Google Scholar 

  104. See ICRA (2004), p. 23; Sunder Ram (2001), p. 54.

    Google Scholar 

  105. Some observers even regard the budget deficits in India as the main source of danger for the reform process. Manor (2005) for example argues that “the main threat to liberalization is not a U-turn, but fiscal indiscipline — budget deficits that result from overspending by ministers.” Manor (2005), p. 102.

    Google Scholar 

  106. See Indian Banks’ Association (2003), p. 17; Mohan (2004), p. 853.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Physica-Verlag Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2008). The Indian banking sector. In: Banking Sector Liberalization in India. Contributions to Economics. Physica-Verlag HD. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-1982-3_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics