Skip to main content

Collusion and multimarket contact in a repeated game

  • Chapter
  • 31 Accesses

Part of the book series: Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung ((BBFDUV,volume 97))

Abstract

The ability of oligopolistic firms tacitly to exploit their potential market power and achieve better outcomes than the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium was first analyzed by Friedman (1971). Friedman argued that in an infinitely repeated game, the threat of future punishment can be used to enforce cooperative behavior. Starting from a collusive output level, duopolists may define future reactions to deviation from that output level (trigger or grim strategies), by which both the deviating and the punishing firm are hurt. Following Friedman, the sustainability of the collusive equilibrium can then be measured by calculating the critical discount factor that equalizes the long term gains from a collusive strategy with the gains from a deviating strategy. In a seminal article, Bernheim / Whinston (1990) claim that multimarket contact may help firms to sustain collusive outcomes whenever firms or markets differ from each other. They consider firms that compete in several markets. It is shown, that the opportunity these firms have to punish deviation from a cooperative equilibrium in every “contact” market may relax binding incentive constraints in a wide range of circumstances. Furthermore, whenever firms differ in their production costs or when scale economies are present, multimarket contact allows the development of “spheres of influence”, which enables firms to sustain higher levels of profits and prices. Bernheim and Whinston assume that markets are independent of one another. The mechanism driving their result is that the ability for multimarket firms to “pool” their incentive constraints across markets allows them to export “slack enforcement power” from one market to the other.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Alexander (1985) was the first who hinted at this implicit assumption. Lee / Tang (1994) developed the idea further, claiming that firms must pursue a corporate strategy if multimarket contact is to be effective and assuming a correlation between lateral diversification and corporate strategy.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Recent work about the importance of the organizational structure was done, however, in a one market context, by Spagnolo (1998), who examines the strategic use of managerial low-powered incentives as a means of sustaining one market collusion.

    Google Scholar 

  3. In accordance with most of the models dealing with (multimarket) collusion, the focus in this analysis will be on stationary equilibria.

    Google Scholar 

  4. This approach will be followed in the subsequent analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  5. This peculiarity resulting from the joint cost term has not been considered so far in the literature.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Appendix E.1. Only if g is positive and very high, might efficient collusive outcomes where one firm monopolizes the collusive market and the other firm concentrates on the other market be possible.

    Google Scholar 

  7. The critical discount factors are equal for both firms, as output is allocated evenly to each firm.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Appendix E.2.

    Google Scholar 

  9. The separation of incentive constraints for both markets can never be optimal. As two market punishment is a more severe punishment for deviation than one market punishment, it relaxes the incentive constraint of firms for each single market. See Appendix E.3 for a proof.

    Google Scholar 

  10. This assumption implies a fair allocation of market shares and equalizes and minimizes the critical discount factors of both firms (min s max min i ** i , δ** j }).

    Google Scholar 

  11. See chapter 3 for efficient output shares in case of joint profit maximization and Appendix E. 4 for output shares that minimize deviation profits.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Appendix E.4.

    Google Scholar 

  13. MATH (see also Appendix E.4).

    Google Scholar 

  14. As firms and divisions symmetrical, it is assumed that both the percentage of divisional profits and the fixed part of managers’ salary are the same in both firms and both divisions.

    Google Scholar 

  15. As divisions do not participate in profits of the other division, a division being allocated a low output share cannot alleviate its disadvantage in its own market by concentrating on a second market. The monopolization of one market by one division is therefore never feasible: punishment profits are alway higher than collusive profits. The minimal discount factor for both firms (for one or two market collusion), min s maxi is obtained for symmetrical output shares. See also Appendix E.5.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Again, this assumption can be made only because s = 1/2.

    Google Scholar 

  17. This is consistent with the approach to ask for the most collusive outcome (see chapter 7.1).

    Google Scholar 

  18. See Appendix E.6

    Google Scholar 

  19. See Appendix E.6

    Google Scholar 

  20. See also Appendix E. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Appendix E.6.

    Google Scholar 

  22. However, as mentioned in chapter 7.2, we do not expect to observe one market collusion in centralized firms if they face diseconomies of scope. Comparing the critical discount factor for two market collusion in centralized firms (δ ** (ŝ)) with the discount factor for one market collusion in decentralized firms (δΦ*) for g > 0 would lead to the result, that collusion in one market in decentralized firms is always more difficult than collusion in (at least) one market in centrailized firms.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See appendix for λ crit>(g)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2001 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Neubauer, S. (2001). Collusion and multimarket contact in a repeated game. In: Multimarket Contact and Organizational Design. Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung, vol 97. Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_7

  • Publisher Name: Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-8244-9063-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-663-05979-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics