Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung ((BBFDUV,volume 97))

  • 32 Accesses

Abstract

Big firms necessarily divide responsibility by means of delegation and divisionalization. A commonly held view is that greater flexibility and a more efficient management which result from flatter hierarchies provide the reason for this development. The literature on strategic delegation explores the strategic incentives for delegation when competitors interact with each other in the marketplace. For example, divisionalization of a one product firm, in which divisions compete with one another, may be a device for achieving a higher market share of the entire market.91 Alternatively, vertical delegation decisions that determine the degree of vertical specialization may affect the strategic position of a firm by affecting variable costs.92

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See Baye / Crocker / Ju (1996). See also Gonzalez-Maestre (1997), who use a three-stage model, where firms can first choose the number of divisions, then in a second stage the incentive schemes for their managers, and managers choose market strategies in the last stage.

    Google Scholar 

  2. See Gal-Or (1993a).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Milgrom / Roberts (1992), p. 414.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Milgrom / Roberts (1992), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  5. According to Milgrom / Roberts (1992), p. 413, in 1988 about 30% of all firms in the United States used to some extent a bonus scheme based on corporate profits (profit-sharing plans).

    Google Scholar 

  6. This is, for example, the case in IBM. See FT November 27 1991, cited in Faulli-0ller / Giralt (1995), p. 79.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Faulli-Oller / Giralt (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Appendix B.3 for a proof.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Williamson (1975), p. 153.

    Google Scholar 

  10. As managers are risk-neutral, one could also assume that managers receive 100 % of their evaluation basis and pay a rent to owners, so that managers remain exactly with their opportunity costs.

    Google Scholar 

  11. The impact of asymmetrical cost allocation schemes will be analyzed in chapter 5.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Fairness / equity of a cost allocation is one of the properties often required in the literature dealing with allocation of joint costs. See for example Jensen (1977), p. 844, Horngren / Foster, p. 459 or Ewert/ Wagenhofer (1993), p. 540 – 546. See also Hughes / Scheiner (1980), p. 86 – 87 who emphasize the existence of a trade-off between behavioral benefits and efficiency criteria.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See also Zimmermann (1979) for a justification of this approach: Zimmermann argues that joint costs should be allocated on the basis of expected utilization of a common resource to approximate to opportunity costs which are difficult to measure.

    Google Scholar 

  14. As firms and divisions are symmetrical, the same fixed wage and the same percentage on profits is necesary to secure managers’ reservation utility. Therefore it can be assumed that, given the bonus base, the fixed part of the salary and the amount of the bonus are the same in both firms and both divisions.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Quantity choices of managers depend also on the parameters g and a, and on the quantity choices in the other market. In the figure, those values are kept constant.

    Google Scholar 

  16. In this case, the symmetrical interior solution yields values for αi which are in the range [0, 1]. There are also asymmetrical solutions where αij) reaches infinity, which will not be considered.

    Google Scholar 

  17. See also Appendix B.1.

    Google Scholar 

  18. See also Appendix B.1.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See Appendix B.2.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Appendix B.2.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2001 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Neubauer, S. (2001). Strategic delegation and multimarket contact. In: Multimarket Contact and Organizational Design. Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung, vol 97. Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_4

  • Publisher Name: Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-8244-9063-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-663-05979-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics