Skip to main content

The impact of multimarket contact on the strategic behavior of firms

  • Chapter
Multimarket Contact and Organizational Design

Part of the book series: Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung ((BBFDUV,volume 97))

  • 31 Accesses

Abstract

The reasons and motives for diversifying into new geographical or product markets differ. The motive for entering multiple markets may be to realize economies of scope in production or administration that result from learning effects or the better use of indivisible resources.4 There may also be economies of scope in demand resulting from the existence of umbrella effects or switching costs5. The inadequacy of external capital markets may induce firms to expand their business in order to create an internal capital market.6 Multimarket operation may be efficient because it reduces the number of market transactions.7 There may also be managerial preferences for growth which — after growth opportunities in the core business have been exploited — can be satisfied only by diversification.8

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. See i.e. Panzar / Willig (1977), for the conceptual framework and Bailey / Friedländer (1982) or Teece (1980) for extensions. See also Porter (1985), chapter 9; Scott (1993) chapter 1; and Cowling (1980).

    Google Scholar 

  2. See Cabral (1988) for the issue of umbrella branding. A similar topic is touched on by Andersson (1998), who explains that in a infinite game framework multiproduct firms will enjoy an advantage from a reputation for high quality. See Klemperer (1992) and (1995) for the concept of switching costs

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Williamson (1975), p. 143 – 148, Scott (1993), p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Williamson (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  5. See Müller (1969), Jensen (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  6. See Edward (1955) and Bernheim / Whinston (1990). See also Axelrod (1981) who stresses that cooperation between rivals can be reduced by fostering specialization, hence avoiding regular interaction between competitors.

    Google Scholar 

  7. For example, if competitor’s costs are stochastic and a firm receives a signal about the size of costs, several signals in different market might increase the signal’s precision. A similar argument, but with stochastic demand, can be found in Gal-Or (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  8. There are two reasons, why multimarket contact increases firms awareness of capabilities or actions of a rival: firstly, when collecting competitors information, multimarket rivals usually receive greater attention than one-market competitors. Secondly multimarket competitors have more prior experiences — in competitive engagements, which are captured in the collective memory of firms as “war stories” (see Weick (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  9. See Porter (198), p. 354.

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Porter (1985) and Karnani / Wernerfelt (1985) for these examples.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See Spagnolo (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Recent literature suggests that mutual forbearance is facilitated by multimarket contact both by a better understanding of rivals’capabilities (familiarity) and by increased retaliation possibilities. However, in accordance with “traditional” forbearance theories, I will discuss the concept of mutual forbearance only in the light of mutual (entry) threats.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Heberle (1948).

    Google Scholar 

  14. For example Scherer/ Ross (1990), Porter in his discussion about the necessity of a horizontal strategy (1985) and Bernheim / Whinston (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  15. See, for example, Kamani / Wernefelt (1985), Chen (1996) and Gimeno / Woo (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  16. See for example Barnett (1993), Baum / Korn (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  17. This happened for example in the tire industry, where Goodyear reacted to Michelin’s invasion in 1969 in its North American home market by entering the European market. Other examples are Maxwell’s attack on the stronghold of Folger as a reaction to Folger’s invasion of Maxwell’s home market. (See Karnani / Wernerfelt (1985) for these examples.)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Note, that a corporate view of one market strategies is necessary without any inherent linkage (cost or demand) between markets.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See, for example, Baum / Korn (1999). See also Burt (1980) who documented in the field of network theory the relative advantages of high degrees of interconnectedness among network actors.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Jayachandran / Gimeno / Varadarajan (1999) for an overview.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Edwards (1955) for this concept.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See also Teece / Pisano / Shuen (1997) for this argument.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See Alexander (1985), Feinberg (1995) and Gimeno / Marin / Woo (1998) for the impact of concentration on intensity of compensation.

    Google Scholar 

  24. The approach of conjectural variations is for example used by Venables (1990). A critique of this approach can be found in Tirole (1993),p. 244 – 245.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See Kantarelis / Veendorp (1988). A problem of this approach is that the restrictions of strategy spaces are exogenous to the model, so that it is unclear why firms behave in this way.

    Google Scholar 

  26. One important exception is Harrington (1987), who analyzes the conditions for stable collusionin a framework of a finitely repeated game.

    Google Scholar 

  27. In contrast to cartel agreements, each firm decides independently about its supply. The choice of a “soft” strategy such as a high price or low supply is the result of individual rational decision making.

    Google Scholar 

  28. See also Pinto (1986) who anticipated their results when there are asymmetric cost conditions, and Bae (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  29. See for example Boehnlein (1995) for horizontal product differentiation, Häckner (1994) for vertical differentiation, Kesteloot (1987) for (dis)economies of scope in demand.

    Google Scholar 

  30. See Spangolo (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  31. See especially Philipps / Mason (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  32. Scott (1982, 1992) and Baum / Korn (1999) additionally showed, that firms may intentionally develop multimarket contact by diversifying into similar industries than their competitors.

    Google Scholar 

  33. See Whitehead (1978), Rhoades / Heggested (1985), and Mester (1987).

    Google Scholar 

  34. See, for example, Feinberg (1985), Hughes / Oughton (1993) and Scott (1982, 1989, 1991).

    Google Scholar 

  35. Further empirical work supporting the forbearance theory was done, for example, Boeker et al. (1997) and Fernandez / Marin (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  36. See, for example, Sandler (1988), Singal (1993), Evans / Kessides (1994), Gimeno / Woo (1996), Baum / Korn (1996, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Parker / Röller (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Jans / Rosenbaum (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  39. See Frese (1993), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Chandler (1962), who characterized these two extreme forms. Oliver Williamson (1970), pp. 120 f, described the M-form as a complex organization that consists of a number of self-contained, semiautonomous divisions, each grouped by reference to some set of criteria (product line, technologies, geography etc.). The counterpart, the U-form is decribed as functionally and hierachially organized, where decisions are taken centrally.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See also Bühner (1993) and Frese (1995), p. 88 for the practical relevance and importance of profitcenter organizations when firms grow in size.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See Albach (1989), p. 19; Milgrom / Roberts (1992), p. 79.

    Google Scholar 

  43. See Goshal / Westney (1993), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See the literature overview in the specific sections.

    Google Scholar 

  45. However, as the existence of resource or market interdependencies play an important role so far as the influence of organizational structures on strategic choices is concerned, the topic of coordination and its impact on internal efficieny will also be implicitly considered.

    Google Scholar 

  46. See Frese (1993) p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  47. See the next section for a literature overview.

    Google Scholar 

  48. This issue is the focus of the principal — agent literature, which will be briefly discussed below.

    Google Scholar 

  49. See for example Schelling (1960), p. 123 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Schelling (1960) also points out the role of identification and mediation.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Schelling (1960), p. 122, 124 claims that commitment to a move is equivalent to moving first.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Schelling (1960), p. 142 for the role of delegation as a commitment device.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Sklivas (1987) and Fershtman / Judd (1987) where among the first who analyzed the strategic effect of delegation.

    Google Scholar 

  54. See Bulow / Geanakoplos / Klemperer (1985) for the concept of strategic substitutes (complements).

    Google Scholar 

  55. This was the idea developed by Sklivas (1987) and Fershtman / Judd (1987). For an empirical analisis of the influence of product market competition (strategic substitutes vs. strategic complements) on the pay-per-performance sensitivity of top management compensation see Kedia (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  56. See Allen (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Polo / Tedeschi (1992). See also Aggarwal / Samwick (1998), who allow contracts which depend positively on rivals’ profits and empirically test the hypothesis that this leads to less rigous competition.

    Google Scholar 

  58. For example Salomon Brothers in 1990 introduced a compensation scheme, which combined divisional performance measures and the companies market value (stock) as a basis for managers evaluation. See Milgrom / Roberts (1992), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Vgl. Faulli — O11er / Giralt (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  60. The use of cost allocation schemes for strategic purposes in multi-product firms was first analyzed by Gal-Or (1993). She showed that it might be profitable for firms that are active in an oligopolistic, as well as in a completely competitive, market to allocate less cost to the division serving the oligopolistic market in order to induce less aggressive reactions by the competitor.

    Google Scholar 

  61. The possibilty of endogenizing the timing strategy was first addressed by Hamilton / Slutzky (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  62. Lorsch / Allen (1973), p. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Frese (1993), p. 29 – 30, 36 for the problem of “decision-interdependency” and the role of information when decisions are interdependent.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Organizational theorists mostly only see the (positive) effect of information on internal coordination (see i.e. Frese (1993)). They neglect the effect on competitors.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Computer-based information systems have for example been introduced in West LB, in Deutsche Lufthansa AG, in Hoechst AG and in retailing firms like Toys “R” Us, Benneton and The Gap . See contributions in Behme / Schimmelpfennig (1993) and the overview in Anand / Mendelson (1997) for examples.

    Google Scholar 

  66. See for example Piechota (1993), p. 86, Picot / Reichwald (1996), p. 135, 184.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Albach (1969) for an overview. See also Marshak / Radner (1972) or more recent publications by Keren / Levhary (1987), Radner (1992) and (1993), Kennedy (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  68. See Hart / Holmström (1987) for a survey of this literature.

    Google Scholar 

  69. ee, for example, Aggarwal / Mandelker (1987) on financing decisions, and Lambert (1986), Campbell / Chan / Marino (1989), Smith / Watts (1992), Hirshleifer / Suh (1992), Bizjak / Brickley / Coles (1993) on investment behaviour.

    Google Scholar 

  70. See for example Lambert / Larcker (1988), Sloan (1993) or Bushman / Indjejikian (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  71. See i.e. Gal-Or (1995) or Aghion / Tirole (1995). See also Sridhar / Balachandran (1997) for a discussion about information structures and their impact on the boundaries of firms.

    Google Scholar 

  72. See Hart (1983), Hermalin (1992) and (1994) or Scharfstein (1988) for the influence of competition on managerial slack. Horn / Lang / Lundgren (1994) and Hermalin (1994) the strategic interactions of firms. In these papers, owners can delegate a task to managers, who invest in cost-reducing effort, but the owners will still play the market game.

    Google Scholar 

  73. See previous section.

    Google Scholar 

  74. The assumption that managers maximize the objective function proposed by owners can also be justified empirically. Murphy (1998) shows that compensation of top managers in most cases depends — in addition to other performance measures — linearly on accounting based profits and on shareholder value. Additionally, research enriching the simple principal-agent model suggests a minor role for input based incentive schemes and a increased benefit of tying salary to principals’ objectives (see Murphy, (1998), p. 29 for this argument). It also leads to incentive structures that are linear rather than convex or concave (Holmström / Milgrom (1991), Hart / Holmström (1987)).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2001 Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag GmbH, Wiesbaden

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Neubauer, S. (2001). The impact of multimarket contact on the strategic behavior of firms. In: Multimarket Contact and Organizational Design. Beiträge zur betriebswirtschaftlichen Forschung, vol 97. Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-663-05979-0_2

  • Publisher Name: Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-8244-9063-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-663-05979-0

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics