Skip to main content

Multiple-Periods Model

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Financial Economics

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 3592 Accesses

Abstract

In the previous two chapters, we have restricted ourselves to the case of two time periods, one for investing and one for receiving payoffs. For many applications it is, however, necessary to allow for models with more than two time periods. In particular one can then study re-trading on the arrival of new information. Nevertheless we will see that many of the insights we have won for the two-period model will be useful also for multi-period models.

“It will fluctuate.” John P. Morgan’s reply, when asked what the stock market will do.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The mathematical term for an event tree is a filtration, \(\mathcal{F}_{0},\mathcal{F}_{1},\mathop{\ldots },\mathcal{F}_{T}\), i.e. a sequence of partitions of a set \(\{1,\mathop{\ldots },s\}\) such that \(\mathcal{F}_{0} =\{\{ 1,\mathop{\ldots },s\}, \varnothing \}\), \(\mathcal{F}_{T} =\{\{ 1\},\{ 2\},\mathop{\ldots },\{s\}\}\) and for all \(e_{t} \in \mathcal{F}_{t}\) there exists \(e_{t-1} \in \mathcal{F}_{t-1}\) such that \(e_{t} \subseteq e_{t-1}\).

  2. 2.

    Note that investors’ preferences are defined over consumption and not over the depot value. The utility function representing the investors’ time preferences and risk attitude determines the consumption, which is smoothed over the realized states.

  3. 3.

    Note that in contrast to Chap. 4, k = 0 does not denote the risk-free asset but consumption. This is because long-lived assets that are re-traded are rarely risk-free since their prices might fluctuate.

  4. 4.

    In principle, all quantities will be dependent on the entire history/path ω t – or at least on the realized state ω t – and we should write, e.g., \(q_{t}^{k}(\omega ^{t})\), as there might be a different path ωt for which \(q_{t}^{k}(\omega '^{t})\) is a different value. Thus, in writing \(q_{t}^{k}\) above we not only name a function where instead its value is meant, but we are not precise on which value we actually mean, either. Doing so is therefore – if not stated differently – understood just as an abbreviation for ease of reading. Please observe that we cannot write q k(t), because there is not “one” function q or q k which gets evaluated at two different points in time: q t and q t+1 are two different functions, as they are defined on two different domains (Ω t: = Ω 0 × ×Ω t and \(\varOmega ^{t+1} =\varOmega ^{t} \times \varOmega _{t+1}\) respectively).

  5. 5.

    The budget constraint is defined over the wealth in period t and t − 1, where the sum \(\sum _{k}\left (\frac{D_{t}^{k}+q_{t}^{k}} {q_{t-1}^{k}} \right )\lambda _{t-1}^{i,k}\) is the compound interest rate.

  6. 6.

    This may arise if there are more states than insurance possibilities.

  7. 7.

    Re-arrange the budget constraints for c, insert the result in the utility function and differentiate with respect to the bond holdings s. Finally, evaluate the marginal utilities at c = w.

  8. 8.

    Note that in reality, the growth rate is unknown while the spot rate curve can be observed at all times. Thus, a falling term structure is typically an indicator for a recession (see [CS09]).

  9. 9.

    Note that s 12 does not depend on the state u or d. This is because the forward contract is written in t = 0 without conditioning on the state realized in t = 1. The amount borrowed/lent will be effective for the budget constraint in t = 1.

  10. 10.

    We give only the strict monotonic variant of arbitrage (compare Chap. 4 for other definitions).

  11. 11.

    In the insurance context, “fair” means that the insurance premium must be equal to the expected damages.

  12. 12.

    We use the same notation as for the similar example given in Chap. 4.

  13. 13.

    To simplify expressions we have assumed a constant interest rate.

  14. 14.

    See [HK78] for more details.

  15. 15.

    Considering different speeds of adjustment in economic dynamics was first suggested by Samuelson [Sam64].

  16. 16.

    In fact, trading is so fast nowadays, that even the physical distance from the stock exchange plays a role, as buying and selling orders are transmitted via cables and since the speed of light and particularly the processing times of signals at switching points are limited, a trading computer on Wall Street can react so much faster than its colleague a few blocks away that the latter does not stand a chance in competing when trying to exploit new information on the short-run.

  17. 17.

    To simplify matters we first suppress all time and uncertainty dependence in this generic one step ahead optimization problem.

  18. 18.

    R s i, k is the return agent i expects to get from asset k if state s occurs.

  19. 19.

    Recall that in Chap. 4 k = 0 was the risk-free asset.

  20. 20.

    I.e. the wealth not consumed, but spent on financial assets.

  21. 21.

    To be mathematically correct one should introduce a different symbol for a utility function if it depends on different variables than before. However, adding more notation will be confusing to many readers.

  22. 22.

    Again, the notation is used: μ(R i) is a vector in \(\mathbb{R}^{k}\) but R f is a scalar. A more correct notation would be \(\mu (\tilde{R}^{i}) - R_{f}\nVdash \), where \(\tilde{R}^{i}\) denotes the matrix of risk assets and \(\nVdash \in \mathbb{R}^{k}\) is a vector with 1 in each entry.

  23. 23.

    The first assumption is not restrictive, since in case two agents were to disagree on the dividends in one of the states, one might introduce more states and let the agents disagree over the occurrence of the states. The second assumption is strong. The only excuse we have is that it is sufficient to generate interesting dynamics – and that it is convenient in the Brock-Homes-Model.

  24. 24.

    For a proof, we show that the iteration \(X_{n+1}:= aX_{n} + b\) always converges if | a |  < 1. To see this, we compute the fixed point of the iteration as \(X = b/(1 - a)\), i.e. if \(X_{n} = b/(1 - a)\) then \(X_{n+1} = X_{n}\). Then we consider the squared difference of X n to the fixed point and show with a small computation that it is decreasing. From this we can deduce that X n indeed converges. We can apply this auxiliary result to the dynamic system above.

  25. 25.

    This result follows from the decreasing marginal utility. The more wealth an investor receives the lower is his marginal utility.

  26. 26.

    Note that up to now we did not make any assumption on how the portfolio strategy \(\lambda _{t}^{i,k}(\omega ^{t})\) executed at ω t is determined!

  27. 27.

    Formally, this identity follows from aggregating \(W_{t}^{i} =\sum _{k}(D_{t}^{k} + q_{t}^{k})\theta _{t-1}^{i,k}\) over all agents noting that \(\sum _{k}q_{t}^{k} = (1 -\lambda ^{c})\sum _{k}W_{t}^{i}\).

  28. 28.

    That is to say on all paths except for those that are highly unlikely, i.e. those that have measure zero according to the probability measure P. For example, if P is i.i.d., every infinite sequence in which some state is not visited infinitely often has measure zero.

References

  1. L.E. Blume and D. Easley, Learning to Be Rational, Journal of Economic Theory 26 (1982), no. 2, 340–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. L. Blume and D. Easley, Evolution and Market Behavior, Journal of Economic Theory 58 (1992), no. 1, 9–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. T. Bewley, The optimum quantity of money, Models of Monetary Economics (1980), 169–210.

    Google Scholar 

  4. W.A. Brock and C.H. Hommes, A Rational Route to Randomness, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society (1997), 1059–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  5. —————, Heterogeneous Beliefs and Routes to Chaos, in a Simple Asset Pricing Model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 22 (1998), 1235–1274.

    Google Scholar 

  6. N. Barberis, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, A Model of Investor Sentiment, Journal of Financial Economics 49 (1998), no. 3, 307–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. L. Chan, J. Karceski, and J. Lakonishok, Momentum Strategies, Journal of Finance 51 (1996), 1681–1711.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. J.H. Cochrane, Asset Pricing, Princeton University Press Princeton, NJ, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  9. G.M. Constantinides, Intertemporal Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers and Without Demand Aggregation, The Journal of Business 55 (1982), no. 2, 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. P. Cootner, Stock Prices: Random vs. Systematic Changes, The random character of stock market prices (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA) (1964), 231–252.

    Google Scholar 

  11. T.M. Cover, An algorithm for maximizing expected log investment return, IEEE ToIT IT-30 (1984), no. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  12. M. Chauvet and Z. Senyuz, A Joint Dynamic Bi-Factor Model of the Yield Curve and the Economy as a Predictor of Business Cycles.

    Google Scholar 

  13. A.C.W. Chui, S. Titman, and K.C.J. Wei, Individualism and Momentum around the World, The Journal of Finance 65 (2010), 361–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. W.F.M. De Bondt and R. Thaler, Does the Stock Market Overreact?, The Journal of Finance 40 (1985), no. 3, 793–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. K. Daniel, D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam, Investor Psychology and Security Market Under-and Overreactions, The Journal of Finance 53 (1998), no. 6, 1839–1885.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. J.B. De Long, A. Shleifer, L.H. Summers, and R.J. Waldmann, Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets, The Journal of Political Economy 98 (1990), no. 4, 703–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Shleifer A. Summers L. De Long, B. and R. Waldmann, The survival of noise traders in financial markets, Journal of Business 64 (1991), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. —————, Dynamic Asset Pricing Theory, Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  19. I. Evstigneev, T. Hens, and K. Schenk-Hoppé, Evolutionary Stable Stock Markets, Economic Theory, Springer Verlag 27 (2006), no. 2, 449–468.

    Google Scholar 

  20. M. Harrison and D. Kreps, Speculative Investor Behavior in a Stock Market with Heterogeneous Expectations, Quaterly Journal of Economics 92 (1978), 323–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. H. Hong and J.C. Stein, A Unified Theory of Underreaction, Momentum Trading, and Overreaction in Asset Markets, The Journal of Finance 54 (1999), no. 6, 2143–2184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. T. Hens and K.R. Schenk-Hoppé, Evolutionary Stability of Portfolio Rules in Incomplete Markets, Journal of Mathematical Economics 41 (2005), 43–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. T. Hens and K.R. Schenk-Hoppé, Handbook of Financial Markets: Dynamics and Evolution, North-Holland, 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  24. N. Jegadeesh and S. Titman, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency, The Journal of Finance 48 (1993), no. 1, 65–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. B. LeBaron, W.B. Arthur, and R. Palmer, Time Series Properties of an Artificial Stock Market, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23 (1999), 1487–1516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. R.E. Lucas Jr, Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy, Econometrica 46 (1978), no. 6, 1429–1445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. C. Lee and B. Swaminathan, Price Momentum and Trading Volume, Journal of Finance 55 (2000), 2017–2069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. J. Lakonishok, A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny, The Impact of Institutional Trading on Stock Prices, Journal of Financial Economics 32 (1992), no. 1, 23–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. —————, Contrarian Investment, Extrapolation, and Risk, The Journal of Finance 49 (1994), no. 5, 1541–1578.

    Google Scholar 

  30. V. De Miguel, L. Garlappi, and R. Uppal, Optimal versus Naive Diversification: How Inefficient Is the 1/N Portfolio Strategy?, Review of Financial Studies 22 (2009), no. 5, 1915–1953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. M. Magill and M. Quinzii, Theory of incomplete markets, The MIT Press, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  32. K.G. Rouwenhorst, International Momentum Strategies, The Journal of Finance 53 (1998), no. 1, 267–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. P. Samuelson, Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems, The Review of Economics and Statistics 46 (1964), no. 2, 145–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. A. Sandroni, Do Markets Favor Agents Able to Make Accurate Predictions?, Econometrica 68 (2000), no. 6, 1303–1341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Handbook of Financial Markets: Dynamics and Evolution, North-Holland, 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  36. D. Schiereck, W. De Bondt, and M. Weber, Contrarian and Momentum Strategies in Germany, Financial Analysts Journal 55 (1999), no. 6, 104–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. H. Shefrin, Beyond Greed and Fear, Harvard Business School Press, 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  38. H.R. Varian, Microeconomic Analysis, 2 nd edition, Norton New York (1978).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hens, T., Rieger, M.O. (2016). Multiple-Periods Model. In: Financial Economics. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-49688-6_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-49688-6_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-662-49686-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-49688-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics