Skip to main content

The WTO’s Effect on Trade: What You Give is What You Get

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Globalization

Abstract

Do countries trade more when they participate in the World Trade Organisation (WTO)? After Rose’s (Am Econ Rev 94:98–114, 2004) initial “non-effect”, the literature has developed in several ways to re-examine this unexpected result. This paper gives a detailed overview of the developments and exposes the main biases that plague previous contributions. Using a dataset covering 181 countries for the period 1948–2007, we show that zero trade flows are best incorporated using (zero-inflated) negative binomial maximum likelihood estimation. We find that formal members gained more than non-member participants, and the level of WTO participants experienced gains go hand in hand with the extent of their multilateral liberalisation commitments. Developed nations gain more than developing or least developed countries, although poor countries do benefit from trading under the Generalised System of Preferences (GSP). We also correct for selection bias with respect to economic integration agreements and find, overall, that regionalism has a lower trade-promoting effect than WTO membership.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The change in international trade volumes induced by WTO participation is what will be called the “WTO effect” throughout this paper.

  2. 2.

    Following the WTO’s practice, this study considers LDCs and developing countries to be two distinct groups of countries.

  3. 3.

    Unfortunately, the aggregate nature of the trade data in the present dataset does not allow for industry-specific analyses. However, studies focusing on a select number of countries, years and industries have found supporting evidence for WTO membership with respect to capital-intensive commodities (Engelbrecht and Pearce, 2007) and trade excluding agriculture, textiles and oil (Kim, 2010).

  4. 4.

    The terms membership and participation are used interchangeably throughout this paper, but the context will be sufficiently specific when distinctions between de jure, formal membership and de facto, informal participation are necessary.

  5. 5.

    Trade at the intensive margin studies the WTO effect on country-pairs that already have a trade relationship. However, WTO membership may also lead to the creation of trade relationships that countries would otherwise not have had, which is referred to as trade at the extensive margin.

  6. 6.

    The former is calculated as \(ln[\frac{1} {4}(export_{ij} + export_{ji} + import_{ij} + import_{ji})]\), the latter as \(ln[(export_{ij} \times export_{ji} \times import_{ij} \times import_{ji})^{\frac{1} {4} }]\).

  7. 7.

    There are no provisions in international law that require governments to notify their EIAs to the WTO before they can be enforced.

  8. 8.

    Baldwin and Taglioni (2006) and Baier and Bergstrand (2007) argue that these “traditional,” time-invariant MRT should actually be time-varying to correct for endogeneity bias, and that it can be included in linear models by estimating importer-time (it), exporter-time (jt) and country-pair (ij) effects. However, the large number of dummies leads to an incidental parameter problem. Although this can be addressed in linear models by de-meaning the data, in this case cancelling the dyad dummies, there is as of yet no straightforward solution for non-linear models.

  9. 9.

    Zero-truncated models are not considered because they only allow for positive trade flows, which does not help to address the zero trade flow problem.

  10. 10.

    Rose’s model specification is slightly different from (5). In particular, he uses the natural logarithm of the product of the importer and exporter’s real GDP. In the remainder of this study, these variables are included separately.

  11. 11.

    MLE is performed using the DFP algorithm (Gould et al., 2006, Chap. 1).

  12. 12.

    Observing variation in countries that have been members since the GATT’s inception is not possible due to data limitations. The trade liberalisation efforts of these countries may have been even more extensive than those of countries that joined later because, being GATT founders, they showed the greatest formal initiative to liberalise trade. This may imply that the obtained estimates of the WTO effect are underestimated, although this seems difficult to verify directly.

References

  • Allison, P., & Waterman, R. (2002). Fixed effects negative binomial regression models. Sociological Methodology, 32, 247–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93, 170–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2007). Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of International Economics, 71, 72–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Taglioni, D. (2006). Gravity for Dummies and Dummies for Gravity Equations. Working Paper 12516. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barton, J. H., Goldstein, J. L., Josling, T. E., & Steinberg, R. H. (2006). The evolution of the trade regime: Politics, law, and economics of the GATT and the WTO. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosker, M. (2008). The Empirical Relevance of Geographical Economics. PhD thesis, Utrecht University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brakman, S., Garita, G., Garretsen, J. H., & van Marrewijk, C.. (2010). Economic and financial integration and the rise of cross-border M&As. In P. A. G. van Bergeijk & S. Brakman (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2008). Consumer price index. http://www.bls.gov/cpi, last accessed November 8, 2008.

  • Burger, M. J., van Oort, F. G., & Linders, G. J. M. (2009). On the specification of the gravity model of trade: Zeros, excess zeros and zero-inflated estimation. Spatial Economic Analysis, 4, 167–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2009). Microeconometrics using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • CEPII. (2008). Geodesic distances. http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm, last accessed November 8, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engelbrecht, H. J., & Pearce, C. (2007). The GATT/WTO has promoted trade, but only in capital-intensive commodities! Applied Economics 39, 1573–1581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C. (2004). Advanced international trade: Theory and evidence. Princeton, MA: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr, G. J., & Kohler, W. (2006). Exploring the intensive and extensive margins of world trade. Review of World Economics, 142, 642–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, W. W., Pitblado, J. S., & Sribney, W. M. (2006). Maximum likelihood estimation with Stata (3rd ed.). College Station, TX: Stata Station.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herz, B., & Wagner, M. (2011). The ‘real’ effect of GATT/WTO - a generalised approach. The World Economy, 34, 1014–1041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilbe, J. M. (2007). Negative binomial regression. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (1995). Direction of trade statistics historical database (1948–1980) CD-ROM. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2008). Direction of trade statistics. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, M. H. (2010). Does the WTO promote trade? Further evidence. Journal of International Trade and Development, 19, 421–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, X. (2009). GATT/WTO promotes trade strongly: Sample selection and model specification. Review of International Economics, 17, 428–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2007). Historical statistics of the world economy: 1–2006 AD. http://www.ggdc.net/maddison, last accessed November 8, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGill. (2009). PTA database. http://ptas.mcgill.ca, last accessed October 3, 2009.

  • Preeg, E. H. (1970). Traders and diplomats: An analysis of the Kennedy Round of negotiations under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. Washington, DC: Brookings Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K. (2004). Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? American Economic Review, 94, 98–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva, J. M. C., & Tenreyoro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 641–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siliverstovs, B., & Schumacher, D. (2009). Estimating gravity equations: To log or not to log? Empirical Economics, 36, 645–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian, A., & Wei, S. (2007). The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly. Journal of International Economics, 72, 151–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swart, J., & van Marrewijk, C. (2009). Cross-border Mergers and Acquisitions: A Piece of the Natural Resource Curse Puzzle. Discussion paper, Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomz, M., Goldstein, J. L., & Rivers, D. (2007). Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? Comment. American Economic Review, 97, 2005–2018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuck. (2009). Trade Agreements Database. http://www.dartmouth.edu/tradedb, last accessed October 3, 2009.

  • UNCTAD. (1974). Operation and effects of the generalized system of preferences.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (1975). Operation and effects of the generalized system of preferences.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (1979). Operation and effects of the generalized system of preferences.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (1981). Operation and effects of the generalized system of preferences.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (1985). Operation and effects of the generalized system of preferences.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2005). Generalized system of preferences: List of beneficiaries.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2006). Generalized system of preferences: List of beneficiaries.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2008). Generalized system of preferences: List of beneficiaries.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Bergeijk, P. A. G., & Brakman, S. (Eds.) (2010). The gravity model in international trade: Advances and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vuong, Q. H. (1989). Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypothese. Econometrica, 57, 307–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (1951). Demographic yearbook 1949–1950. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2011a). Classification of economics by income and region. http://data.worldbank.org/about/country-classifications/country-and-lending-groups, last accessed December 18, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2011b). Development indicators. http://data.worldbank.org/indicator, last accessed December 18, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2011c). Global preferential trade agreements database. http://wits.worldbank.org/gptad, last accessed December 18, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • WorldTradeLaw.net. (2009). FTA database. http://www.worldtradelaw.net/fta/ftadatabase/ftas.asp, last accessed October 3, 2009.

  • WTO. (2011a). Regional trade agreements information system. http://rtais.wto.org, last accessed December 18, 2011.

  • WTO. (2011b). Understanding the WTO. http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/tif_e.htm, last accessed December 18, 2011.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Rob Alessie, Jeff Bergstrand, Maarten Bosker, Steven Brakman, Bob Ethier, Marco Fugazza, Harry Garretsen, Michael Koetter, Suzanne Kok, Xuepeng Liu, Roger Smeets, Peter van Bergeijk, participants at the Seminar on Regionalism in an Integrating World Economy (Utrecht) and the European Trade Study Group Annual Conference (Lausanne), and an anonymous referee for insightful discussions and helpful comments on previous drafts.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tristan Kohl .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kohl, T. (2017). The WTO’s Effect on Trade: What You Give is What You Get. In: Christensen, B., Kowalczyk, C. (eds) Globalization. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-49502-5_19

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-49502-5_19

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-662-49500-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-49502-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics