Skip to main content

Part of the book series: China-EU Law Series ((CELS,volume 2))

  • 543 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter addresses business restrictions (defined as restrictions to alternative business structures and multi-disciplinary practices) in the legal professions. These restrictions are evaluated both from an economic perspective and in relation to the EU legal framework on free movement of legal professions. A central question in this chapter is whether there is a case for further EU intervention. In the context of this book, this chapter therefore deals with questions of regulation (do we need business restrictions from an economic perspective?) and market integration (is harmonization of different national laws necessary?). Finally, this chapter provides some implications for China.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    According to Mullerat (2000, p. 481), MDPs are characterized by the following: they provide more than one professional service; they include lawyers as partners, directors or share owners; and there is profit sharing between members of more than one profession.

  2. 2.

    See with respect to Europe, e.g. Paterson et al. (2003), pp. 49 and 56.

  3. 3.

    European Commission (2003a), pp. 12–13.

  4. 4.

    Examples are the OFT in the UK and the Canadian Competition Bureau. See Philipsen and Olaerts (2010), Chapter 3.

  5. 5.

    Case C-309/99, J.C.J. Wouters, J.W. Savelbergh and Price Waterhouse Belastingadviseurs BV v Algemene Raad van de Nederlandse Orde van Advocaten, 19 February 2002, paras 86–90. Eventually the ECJ decided that the regulation concerned did not infringe European competition rules, since the ban on MDPs could have reasonably been considered necessary for the proper practice of the legal profession as organized in the Netherlands (para. 110).

  6. 6.

    See Panteia and Maastricht University (2012).

  7. 7.

    This is in line with the terminology used e.g., in Panteia and Maastricht University (2012).

  8. 8.

    Panteia and Maastricht University (2012), pp. 196–198. The report includes a table with the rules on ABSs and MDPs per jurisdiction.

  9. 9.

    The term ‘market failure’ refers to perceived shortcomings of the market system itself to deal with certain problems that prevent an economically efficient outcome in a market.

  10. 10.

    Economists would say that regulation is directed towards an improvement in social welfare. For details, see Philipsen (2003), pp. 10–18.

  11. 11.

    Some professional services can be considered as ‘trust goods’, which are characterized by the fact that consumers cannot judge their qualities even after consumption. See on this also the contribution to this book by Shen and Philipsen, Sect. 4.1.

  12. 12.

    See Akerlof (1970).

  13. 13.

    These are the well-known problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. For further details and a discussion of the practical relevance of adverse selection and moral hazard in the market for legal services, see Van den Bergh (2007), pp. 20–22; Garoupa (2008), pp. 467–468; and Philipsen (2010), pp. 205–206.

  14. 14.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 22; Philipsen (2003), pp. 17–19.

  15. 15.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 24; Philipsen (2010), pp. 206–207.

  16. 16.

    This approach has developed from different theories, such as public choice, capture theory and the ‘Chicago’ theory of regulation. For descriptions and references, see Philipsen (2003), pp. 23–27.

  17. 17.

    Economists would say that the transaction costs of professional associations are low, while the information costs of the public at large of finding out about the detrimental effects of (too) restrictive regulation are high. Olson (1965). See also Van den Bergh (2007), pp. 25–26; and Garoupa (2008), p. 470.

  18. 18.

    Philipsen (2010), pp. 207–208. Attempts at an empirical analysis of regulation in the legal services markets include Faure (2003), Paterson et al. (2003), Pagliero (2005), and the studies mentioned in Stephen and Love (2000).

  19. 19.

    This subsection draws heavily from Philipsen (2014b), Section 6.4.1.

  20. 20.

    OECD (2000), p. 26; Van den Bergh (2007), p. 50.

  21. 21.

    For more details, see Philipsen (2009).

  22. 22.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 50.

  23. 23.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 50. See also Grout (2005), who finds it difficult to understand the assumption that there is a distinction between the incentives of lawyers working together and their incentives when they are owned or majority managed by non-lawyers.

  24. 24.

    See also Copenhagen Economics (2006, p. 15), where it is mentioned that outside owners might have better access to capital, are better at reducing costs or better at developing new business ideas.

  25. 25.

    OECD (2000), pp. 26–27.

  26. 26.

    Garoupa (2008), p. 483, referring to Hansmann (1990).

  27. 27.

    See also Garoupa (2008), p. 484. A related issue put forward by Garoupa is that of in-house lawyers, as found in large companies and banks. Because in-house counsel improves business compliance and reduces information asymmetry between corporations and external lawyers, there is no obvious public interest argument to restrict the legal activity of in-house lawyers.

  28. 28.

    Copenhagen Economics (2006), p. 49.

  29. 29.

    Copenhagen Economics (2006), p. 15. However, this particular statement is not backed by any arguments based on economic theory or empirical evidence.

  30. 30.

    Copenhagen Economics (2006), p. 15.

  31. 31.

    Grout (2005), p. 2.

  32. 32.

    Grout (2005), p. 2.

  33. 33.

    Grout (2005), pp. 2–3. In the paper some empirical evidence is presented to back the distinction between small and large firms. This evidence according to the author shows that ‘misconduct and poor quality is heavily focused on small businesses’ (see pp. 31–32).

  34. 34.

    Van den Bergh (2007), pp. 49–50.

  35. 35.

    See also Mullerat (2000), p. 482.

  36. 36.

    Mullerat (2000), pp. 482–483. The author (p. 492) furthermore argues that MDPs represent ‘a new step in the deprofessionalization’ and commercialization of the legal profession.

  37. 37.

    For an extensive analysis of LDPs, see Clementi (2004), pp. 108–128.

  38. 38.

    See for example the analysis of the Wouters case in Sect. 3 below, where it is pointed out the accountancy market is much more concentrated than the legal services market. See also Mullerat (2000).

  39. 39.

    Fox (2000), p. 1097.

  40. 40.

    Fox (2000), pp. 1100–1101.

  41. 41.

    Garoupa (2008), p. 483. Furthermore, Carr and Matthewson (1990, p. 328) found that partnerships dominate sole practitioners when client cases are large and the detection of chiselling is low.

  42. 42.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 49.

  43. 43.

    Stephen and Love (2000), p. 1005.

  44. 44.

    Garoupa (2008), p. 483. Fox (2000, pp. 1105–1106) is not optimistic about the concept of one-stop shopping, claiming that it (and lawyers working for nonlawyers) reduces the legal profession to yet ‘another profit center at a department store for consulting services’.

  45. 45.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 49.

  46. 46.

    Van den Bergh (2007), p. 49.

  47. 47.

    It should be noted with respect to MDPs consisting of lawyers and accountants, that there have been many changes in the (now stricter) regulation of the latter profession, in particular with regard to audit services. This includes rules on auditors’ independence, auditor rotation and quality of accounting services. See Philipsen (2009, 2012).

  48. 48.

    Van den Bergh (2007), pp. 49–50.

  49. 49.

    Mullerat (2000). See also Scott and Konsta (1999).

  50. 50.

    See also Deards (2002).

  51. 51.

    This subsection draws heavily from Philipsen (2014b), Section 6.4.2.

  52. 52.

    See also Fox (2000), pp. 1104–1108, who mentions a lack of empirical evidence, but also (implicitly) suggests that the information asymmetry between business clients and professionals is too large to generate reliable results.

  53. 53.

    Studies on the effects of ownership rules, mergers and accountancy scandals on concentration in the audit market have been performed by GAO (2003) for the U.S., and Oxera (2006, 2007) for the U.K. See also Philipsen (2009) in a report for the OECD.

  54. 54.

    Clementi (2004, pp. 133–134). Clementi also suggests, without quoting specific research, that e.g. in the context of claims arising out of motor accidents, MDPs could offer an integrated service, dealing with property damage, health, rehabilitation and compensation. Another example are affinity groups such as trade unions, which provide a range of legal services to their members, including legal advice.

  55. 55.

    Stephen and Love (2000), p. 1009; Van den Bergh (2007), p. 50.

  56. 56.

    See also Indecon and London Economics (2003), p. 48.

  57. 57.

    Indecon and London Economics (2003), p. 47. See also Van den Bergh (2007), p. 51.

  58. 58.

    Liang and Ogur (1987), p. 3.

  59. 59.

    The author mentions the Establishment Directive (98/5/EC) and (to a lesser extent) the Mutual Recognition Directive (89/48/EEC). Citizens of a Member State refused entry to the legal profession could qualify in another Member State and thereafter practice in the restrictive state, as long as the costs of this procedure are compensated by the gains from practicing in the restrictive state. Any practice rules designed to restrict competition between lawyers in one jurisdiction, thereby raising fee levels, will attract lawyers from other jurisdictions where fees are lower, according to Stephen (2002), p. 118.

  60. 60.

    Stephen (2002), p. 115.

  61. 61.

    Stephen (2002), p. 124.

  62. 62.

    Cases C-35/99 (Arduino) and C-309/99 (Wouters), both decided on 19 February 2002 and dealing with competition issues in the legal services market.

  63. 63.

    For details, see Terry (2009) and Philipsen (2010).

  64. 64.

    Paterson et al. (2003).

  65. 65.

    European Commission (2003b), p. 9.

  66. 66.

    European Commission (2004).

  67. 67.

    European Commission (2004).

  68. 68.

    European Commission (2003a), p. 7.

  69. 69.

    European Commission (2003a), pp. 12–13.

  70. 70.

    This case study was part of a wider study on free movement of lawyers: see Panteia and Maastricht University (2012). The idea of this case study was to involve professionals who are not lawyers. In other parts of the research, interviews were held with lawyers themselves.

  71. 71.

    Attempts were made also to contact professional organizations in Luxemburg, but these attempts were unsuccessful.

  72. 72.

    The interview with two anonymous respondents from the CFE (held 12 July 2012) made clear that German MDPs face similar problems.

  73. 73.

    Interview with anonymous respondent working as a notary in a big Dutch law firm, 23 August 2012. It was noted furthermore that lawyers in Luxemburg (and to a lesser extent in Belgium) operate almost like a cartel. They are not interested in co-operation with notaries.

  74. 74.

    Interview with anonymous respondent from the Royal Netherlands Notarial Organisation KNB, 16 July 2012.

  75. 75.

    Interview with two anonymous respondents from the CFE (held 12 July 2012).

  76. 76.

    Interview with two anonymous respondents from the CFE (held 12 July 2012).

  77. 77.

    Panteia and Maastricht University (2012), pp. 199–200. The authors, however, do not consider the ‘free movement’ argument very convincing, as it is for the country of origin to supervise whether the structural requirements are met which are imposed upon the ABS under home country law; bars in other Member States, where the ABS is active temporarily or in established form, are faced with the supervision of such activities only from the point of view of host country regulation, which is not different from the supervision of host country law firms.

  78. 78.

    And it is well-known that the goals of efficiency and market integration may conflict. See e.g. Bishop and Walker (2010).

  79. 79.

    E.g. OFT (2001), Competition Authority (2006), NMa (2006) and Competition Bureau (2007).

  80. 80.

    See on the market integration rationale also other contributions to this book, including the chapter ‘Introduction’.

  81. 81.

    The study consisted of country studies in all (then) 27 EU Member States (including legal desk research and interviews with national organizations), interviews with representative organizations at the EU level, interviews with law firms, 21 qualitative case studies, and a web survey among lawyers. The focus of the study was on implementation of the Lawyers’ Directives, evaluating these directives (also in relation to the Services Directive and the Qualifications Directive), and on identifying any remaining barriers to free movement of lawyers across the EU.

  82. 82.

    Panteia and Maastricht University (2012), p. 5. Besides these two Lawyers’ Directives, lawyers can also make use of the general system of Directive 2005/36 (on the recognition of professional qualifications), which leads to full integration in the profession of the receiving Member State, if the lawyer concerned successfully completes an aptitude test. The Lawyers’ Establishment Directive also offers a possibility to integrate fully in the legal profession, without the need to do an aptitude test, but only after the lawyer concerned has practiced for 3 years in the receiving country under the system of the Establishment Directive.

  83. 83.

    The rather difficult drafting of Article 11 has led to considerable problems of implementation in the Member States. A violation observed in many Member States is the need to objectively justify application of the host Member State’s professional rules with regard to branch offices and agencies. Member States either completely ignore the requirement or explicitly state that their own professional rules shall apply. A possible reason for this is the unclear wording of Article 11 (5) and its complex relationship with Article 11 (1). See Claessens (2008), p. 238.

  84. 84.

    Maastricht University and Panteia (2014), p. 96.

  85. 85.

    Twenty-one of such qualitative case studies were conducted on specific topics (including those on MDPs and ABSs: see Sect. 3.2 above). In the context of these case studies, 76 interviews were held.

  86. 86.

    Panteia and Maastricht University (2012).

  87. 87.

    See also Maastricht University and Panteia (2014), Chapter 3.

  88. 88.

    Maastricht University and Panteia (2014), p. 136.

  89. 89.

    For more information on the competition law perspective, see e.g. Philipsen (2012).

  90. 90.

    In Maastricht University and Panteia (2014), we again held interviews with various professional associations (including those for legal professions), asking them for justifications with regard to legal form requirements and shareholding requirements, respectively. The justifications mentioned are very similar to those found in previous reports, as far as the legal professions are concerned. See Maastricht University and Panteia (2014), pp. 113–114.

  91. 91.

    Panteia and Maastricht University (2012).

  92. 92.

    See also Articles 15 and 16 of the Services Directive (2006/123/EC).

  93. 93.

    And more generally with the subsidiarity principle.

  94. 94.

    See also Sect. 2.3 above.

  95. 95.

    UM and Panteia (2014), Chapter 8. The report is still under embargo; more details cannot be provided here.

  96. 96.

    It should be stressed that in the EU the ‘internal market goal’ exists alongside the goal of economic efficiency and other goals such as non-discrimination and consumer protection, which provides the EU with another theoretical argument to intervene in the legal services market. This ‘internal market goal’, however, may conflict with economic efficiency.

  97. 97.

    See generally Van den Bergh (2000), Faure (2003), and Van Boom (2011). See also the work by Bruno Frey on functionally overlapping and competing jurisdictions—FOCJ: e.g. Frey (2009).

  98. 98.

    Moreover, people have the options of voice or exit to influence decision making. See Tiebout (1956) and Faure (2003). Furthermore, having different laws rather than one allows for regulatory competition.

  99. 99.

    Which, as stated earlier, is the topic of our current study for DG MARKT.

  100. 100.

    See Philipsen (2014a).

  101. 101.

    Article 7 of The Regulatory Method of Law Firms (2008) Si Fa Bu Lv Shi Shi Wu Shuo Guan Li Ban Fa.

  102. 102.

    Article 9.

  103. 103.

    Article 10.

  104. 104.

    Article 8.

  105. 105.

    Report on Social Responsibilities of Chinese Legal Practitioners (中国律师行业社会责任报告), at http://www.acla.org.cn/html/xinwen/20130827/11102.html. Accessed 10 Mar 2015.

  106. 106.

    Ibid.

  107. 107.

    See also Panteia and Maastricht University (2012) for an explanation of why lawyers want to provide services abroad or establish in another Member State.

  108. 108.

    Liu (2012), Chapter 1.

  109. 109.

    For a detailed analysis of developments in the UK legal services market, see Stephen (2013).

References

  • Akerlof G (1970) The market for lemons: quality, uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q J Econ 85:488–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop S, Walker M (2010) The economics of EC competition law: concepts, application and measurement, 3rd edn. Sweet & Maxwell, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Button K, Fleming M (1992) The effects of regulatory reform on the architectural profession in the United Kingdom. Int Rev Law Econ 12:95–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr J, Matthewson F (1990) The economics of law firms: a study in the legal organization of firms. J Law Econ 33:307–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S (2008) Free movement of lawyers in the European Union. PhD dissertation, Maastricht University, Maastricht

    Google Scholar 

  • Clementi D (2004) Review of the regulatory framework for legal services in England and Wales. Final report. http://www.avocatsparis.org/Presence_Internationale/Droit_homme/PDF/Rapport_Clementi.pdf. Accessed 12 Jan 2015

  • Competition Authority (2006) Competition in professional services: solicitors & barristers. Dublin

    Google Scholar 

  • Competition Bureau (2007) Self-regulated professions: balancing competition and regulation. Gatineau, QC

    Google Scholar 

  • Copenhagen Economics (2006) The legal profession: competition and liberalisation. Copenhagen, January

    Google Scholar 

  • Deards E (2002) Closed shop versus one stop shop: the battle goes on. Eur Law Rev 27:618–627

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2003a) Invitation to comment. Regulation in liberal professions and its effects: summary of responses. Competition DG, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2003b) Stocktaking exercise on regulation of professional services: overview of regulation in the EU Member States. Competition DG, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2004) Stocktaking exercise on regulation of professional services: overview of regulation in the new EU Member States. Competition DG, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Faure M (2003) How law and economics may contribute to the harmonisation of tort law in Europe. In: Zimmerman R (ed) Grundstrukturen des Europäischen Deliktsrechts. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 31–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox LJ (2000) Accountants, the hawks of the professional world: they foul our nest and theirs too, plus other ruminations on the issue of MDPs. Minnesota Law Rev 84:1097–1113

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey BS (2009) A new concept of European federalism. LSE ‘Europe in Question’ discussion paper series, LEQS paper no. 03/2009, London School of Economics and Political Science, London

    Google Scholar 

  • GAO (2003) Public accounting firms: mandated study on consolidation and competition. GAO-03-864, Report to the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs and the House Committee on Financial Services. United States Government Accountability Office, Washington, DC, July

    Google Scholar 

  • Garoupa N (2008) Providing a framework for reforming the legal profession: insights from the European experience. Eur Bus Organ Law Rev 9:463–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grout PA (2005) The Clementi report: potential risks of external ownership and regulatory responses: a report to the Department of Constitutional Affairs. CPMO working paper series no. 05/135, University of Bristol, July

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann H (1990) When does worker ownership work? ESOPs, law firms, codetermination and economic democracy. Yale Law J 99:1749–1816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indecon, London Economics (2003) Indecon’s assessment of restrictions in the supply of professional services, prepared for the Competition Authority. Indecon International Economic Consultants and London Economics, Dublin/London, March

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang N, Ogur JD (1987) Restrictions on dental auxiliaries: an economic policy analysis. Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu YP (2012) The regulation of legal practitioners. Chinese University of Law and Politics Press, Bei Jing (刘宇平《律师法学》中国政法大学出版社:北京, 2012。)

    Google Scholar 

  • Maastricht University, Panteia (2014) Inventory of legal form and shareholding requirements in the EU services sector and their economic assessment. Report for European Commission/DG Internal Market and Services. Maastricht-Zoetermeer, 29 January

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews RCO (1991) The economics of professional ethics: should the professions be more like business? Econ J 101:737–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullerat R (2000) The multidisciplinary practice of law in Europe. J Legal Educ 50(4):481–493

    Google Scholar 

  • NMa (2006) Inventarisatie vrije beroepen: Advocatuur. Nederlandse Mededingingsautoriteit, Den Haag, October

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2000) Competition in professional services, DAFFE/CLP/(2000)2. Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs, Committee on Competition Law and Policy, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OFT (2001) Competition in professions. Report by the Director General of Fair Trading. Office of Fair Trading, March

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxera (2006) Competition and choice in the UK audit market. Prepared for Department of Trade and Industry and Financial Reporting Council. Oxera Consulting Ltd, Oxford, April

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxera (2007) Ownership rules of audit firms and their consequences for audit market concentration. Final Report prepared for DG Internal Market and Services. Oxera Consulting Ltd, Oxford, October. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/auditing/docs/market/oxera_report_en.pdf. Accessed 12 Jan 2015

  • Pagliero M (2005) What is the objective of professional licensing? Evidence from the US market for lawyers. Job Market Paper. London Business School, London, and University of Turin, Turin

    Google Scholar 

  • Panteia, UM (2012) Evaluation of the legal framework for the free movement of lawyers. Report for European Commission/DG Internal Market and Services. Zoetermeer – Maastricht, 28 November. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/qualifications/docs/studies/2013-lawyers/report_en.pdf. Accessed 12 Jan 2015

  • Paterson I, Fink M, Ogus A et al (2003) Economic impact of regulation in the field of liberal professions in different Member States: regulation of professional services. Study for the European Commission. Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ (2003) Regulation of and by pharmacists in the Netherlands and Belgium: an economic approach. Intersentia, Antwerpen-Groningen

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ (2009) Competition and regulation in auditing and related professions, DAF/COMP(2009)19. OECD, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Competition Committee, Paris. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/8/8/44762253.pdf. Accessed 12 Jan 2015

  • Philipsen NJ (2010) Regulation and competition in the legal profession: developments in the EU and China. J Competition Law Econ 6(2):203–231. doi:10.1093/joclec/nhp009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ (2012) Regulation of accountants. In: Van den Bergh R, Pacces AM (eds) Encyclopedia of law and economics: regulation and economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 715–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ (2014a) Limiting auditors’ liability: the case for (and against) EU intervention. Geneva Papers 39:585–597

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ (2014b) Recent developments in the regulation of auditors: an economic perspective. In: Philipsen NJ, Xu G (eds) The role of law and regulation in sustaining financial markets. Routledge, Oxon/New York, pp 127–149

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen NJ, Olaerts M (2010) Restrictions on MDPs and business organization in the legal professions: a literature survey. Report for the MDP committee of the International Bar Association. Maastricht University, ICGI/Metro, Maastricht

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott A, Konsta S (1999) Chinese walls. Accountancy 123:92–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephen FH (2002) The European Single Market and the regulation of the legal profession: an economic analysis. Managerial Decis Econ 23:115–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephen FH (2013) Lawyers, markets and regulation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham/Northampton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stephen FH, Gillanders DD (1993) Ex post monitoring versus ex ante screening in the new institutional economics. J Inst Theor Econ 149:725–730

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephen FH, Love JH (2000) Regulation of the legal profession. In: Bouckaert B, De Geest G (eds) Encyclopedia of law and economics, vol III, The regulation of contracts. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 987–1017

    Google Scholar 

  • Terry LS (2009) The European Commission project regarding competition in professional services. Northwestern J Int Law Bus 29(1); Penn State Legal Studies Research Paper No. 10-2009. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1374855. Accessed 12 Jan 2015

  • Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. J Polit Econ 56:416–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Boom W (2011) Harmonizing tort law: a comparative tort law and economics analysis. In: Faure M (ed) Tort law and economics, Encyclopedia of law and economics, 2nd edn. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham/Northampton, pp 435–449

    Google Scholar 

  • Van den Bergh R (2000) Towards an institutional legal framework for regulatory competition in Europe. Kyklos 53:435–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Bergh R (2007) Towards better regulation of the legal professions. In: OECD, Competitive restrictions in legal professions, DAF/COMP(2007)39, OECD: Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Competition Committee, Paris, pp 17–71

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Niels Philipsen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Additional information

An early version of this paper was presented at the workshop ‘The Professions between Competition and Regulation: Interdisciplinary Perspectives’, Paris, 27–28 September 2013, University Paris Ouest Nanterre La Défense. Disclaimer: parts of this the paper are based on contract research that Niels Philipsen (with colleagues) has conducted for the European Commission/DG MARKT and for the International Bar Association. In the framework of these studies, interviews were held with professional associations and professionals, legal inventories were made, and economic analyses were carried out. One of the studies is under embargo and not all of its results can be published here.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Philipsen, N., Zhou, Q. (2016). Business Restrictions in the Legal Professions: Do We Need More Market Integration?. In: Philipsen, N., Weishaar, S., Xu, G. (eds) Market Integration: The EU Experience and Implications for Regulatory Reform in China. China-EU Law Series, vol 2. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-48273-5_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics