Skip to main content

Abstract

This chapter deals with a crucial step in the decision aiding process: the aggregation of the alternatives’ performances on each criterion in order to faithfully model the overall preference of the decision maker. The approach we follow is that of conjoint measurement, which aims at determining under which conditions a preference can be represented in a particular aggregation model. This approach is first illustrated with the classical additive value function model. Then, we describe two broad families of preference models, which constitute a framework encompassing many aggregation models used in practice. The aggregation rules that fit with the second family of models rely on the aggregation of preference differences. Among this family we find, in particular, models for the outranking relations (concordance relations with vetoes) that are used in several case studies in this book.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

     This postulates the extension to all the Cartesian product X of the preference relation that is perceived on \(\overline{g}(A) = \left \{(g_{1}(a),\ldots,g_{n}(a)),\ a \in A\right \}\). In practice, such an extension could force the client to compare alternatives that appear artificial or unrealistic to him. Despite possible unwanted practical consequences and provided that the range X i is not unrealistic, we consider that the extension of \(\succapprox\) to X is not an outrageous assumption.

  2. 2.

    In reality, these values have been determined by means of another elicitation method; details are provided in Bouyssou et al. (2000, ch. 6).

  3. 3.

     For further discussion of the transitivity of preference issue, mainly in the context of decision under risk, the reader could see Fishburn (1991a). For counter-arguments against considering intransitive preferences, see (Luce, 2000, section 2.2).

  4. 4.

     In case of a tie, i.e. whenever \((x_{i},y_{i})\sim _{i}^{{\ast}}(z_{i},w_{i})\), one has however to look explicitly at the relation between the reverse differences \((y_{i},x_{i})\) and \((w_{i},z_{i})\) since all cases (\(\succapprox _{i}^{{\ast}}\), \(\sim _{i}^{{\ast}}\) or \(\precapprox _{i}^{{\ast}}\)) can possibly show up.

  5. 5.

     The lexicographic preference described in Sect. 3.4.5.4 enters into this framework but can be seen as a limit case.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Cowles Foundations and Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D. (1986). Some remarks on the notion of compensation in MCDM. European Journal of Operational Research, 26, 150–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2002a). A characterization of strict concordance relations. In D. Bouyssou, É. Jacquet-Lagrèze, P. Perny, R. Słowinski, D. Vanderpooten, & Ph. Vincke (Eds.), Aiding decisions with multiple criteria: Essays in honour of Bernard Roy (pp. 121–145). Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2002b) Nontransitive decomposable conjoint measurement. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 46, 677–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2004). Preferences for multi-attributed alternatives: Traces, dominance and numerical representations. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 48(3), 167–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2005). A characterization of concordance relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 167, 427–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2009). An axiomatic analysis of concordance-discordance relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 199, 468–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Vansnick, J.-Cl. (1986). Noncompensatory and generalized noncompensatory preference structures. Theory and Decision, 21, 251–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., Marchant, Th., Pirlot, M., Perny, P., Tsoukiàs, A., & Vincke, Ph. (2000). Evaluation and decision models: A critical perspective. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., Marchant, Th., Pirlot, M., Tsoukiàs, A., & Vincke, Ph. (2006) Evaluation and decision models with multiple criteria: Stepping stones for the analyst. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brans, J.P., & Vincke, Ph. (1985) A preference ranking organisation method. (The PROMETHEE method for multiple criteria decision-making). Management Science, 31(6), 647–656.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1960) Topological methods in cardinal utility theory. In K. J. Arrow, S. Karlin, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in the social sciences (pp. 16–26). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, D., & Fortemps, Ph. (1999). Computing improved optimal solutions to max-min flexible constriant satisfaction problems. European Journal of Operational Research, 118, 95–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, D., Fargier, H., & Prade, H. (1995). Fuzzy constraints in job-shop scheduling. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 6, 215–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, D., Fargier, H., Perny, I., & Prade, H. (2003). A characterization of generalized concordance rules in multicriteria decision-making. International Journal of Intelligent Systems, 18(7), 751–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, W. (1971). Social utilities. Engineering Economist, 6, 119–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1967). Methods of estimating additive utilities. Management Science, 13(7), 435–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1970). Utility theory for decision making. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1976). Noncompensatory preferences. Synthese, 33, 393–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1990a). Continuous nontransitive additive conjoint measurement. Mathematical Social Sciences, 20, 165–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1990b). Additive non-transitive preferences. Economic Letters, 34, 317–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1991a). Nontransitive preferences in decision theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 4, 113–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1991b). Nontransitive additive conjoint measurement. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 35, 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, W. M. (1991). Decomposable threshold models. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 35, 64–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greco, S., Matarazzo, B., & Słowiński, R. (1991). Rough approximation of a preference relation by dominance relations. European Journal of Operational Research, 117, 63–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greco, S., Matarazzo, B., & Słowiński, R. (2001, 30 May–2 June). Axiomatic basis of noncompensatory preferences. In Communication to FUR X, Torino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeney, R. L. (1992). Value-focused thinking. A path to creative decision making. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decisions with multiple objectives: Preferences and value tradeoffs. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krantz, D. H. (1964). Conjoint measurement: The Luce-Tukey axiomatization and some extensions. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 1, 248–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krantz, D. H., Luce, R. D., Suppes, P., & Tversky, A. (1971). Foundations of measurement, vol. 1: Additive and polynomial representations. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D. (1956). Semiorders and a theory of utility discrimination. Econometrica, 24, 178–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D. (2000). Utility of gains and losses: Measurement-theoretic and experimental approaches. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D., Tukey, J. W. (1964). Simultaneous conjoint measurement: A new type of fundamental measurement. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 1, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perny, P. (1992). Modélisation, agrégation et exploitation de préférences floues dans une problématique de rangement. Thèse de doctorat, Université Paris Dauphine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raiffa, H. (1969, December). Preference for multi-attributed alternatives. RAND Memorandum, RM-5868-DOT/RC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1968). Classement et choix en présence de points de vue multiples (la méthode ELECTRE). RIRO, 2, 57–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1971). Problems and methods with multiple objective functions. Mathematical Programming, 1, 239–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1991). The outranking approach and the foundations of ELECTRE methods. Theory and Decision, 31, 49–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1996). Multicriteria methodology for decision aiding. Dordrecht: Kluwer. Original version in French (1985). Méthodologie multicritère d’aide à la décision. Paris: Economica.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B., & Bouyssou, D. (1993). Aide multicritère à la décision : méthodes et cas. Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B., & Vanderpooten, D. (1996). The european school of mcda: Emergence, basic features and current works. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 5(1), 22–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Review, 76, 31–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vansnick, J. Cl. (1986). De Borda et Condorcet à l’agrégation multicritère. Ricerca Operativa, 40, 7–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vincke, Ph. (1992). Multicriteria decision-aid. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vind, K. (1991). Independent preferences. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 20, 119–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Winterfeldt, D., & Edwards, W. (1986). Decision analysis and behavorial research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (1989). Additive representations of preferences: A new foundation of decision analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, P. P. (1991). Additive representations of preferences, a new foundation of decision analysis; the algebraic approach. In J.-P. Doignon & J.-Cl. Falmagne (Eds.), Mathematical psychology: Current developments (pp. 71–87). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thierry Marchant .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bouyssou, D., Marchant, T., Pirlot, M., Tsoukiàs, A., Vincke, P. (2015). Modelling Preferences. In: Bisdorff, R., Dias, L., Meyer, P., Mousseau, V., Pirlot, M. (eds) Evaluation and Decision Models with Multiple Criteria. International Handbooks on Information Systems. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-46816-6_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics