Advertisement

Complex Systems and the Evolution of Human Society

  • Klaus Mainzer
Chapter
  • 149 Downloads

Abstract

How can one explain the emergence of political, social, and economic order in human societies? The chapter starts with a short history of political and economical systems since classical antiquity. The historical ideas of political and economical order were often illustrated by technical, physical, or biological concepts of their corresponding period. In the 17th century, Thomas Hobbes tried to transfer Galilean and Cartesian laws of movement from mechanics to anthropology and state theory. The physiocrates modeled the economic system of an absolutist state like a mechanistic 18th-century clockwork (Sect. 6.1). The liberal ideas of Locke, Hume, and Smith were designed against the historical background from Newton’s physics. Until recent years, mainstream economics has often been inspired by models from linear mathematics, classical mechanics, thermodynamics of thermal equilibrium and sometimes the Darwinian theory of evolution. Like many physicists, economists believed in the exact computability of their (linear) models and suppressed the possibility of a “butterfly effect” leading to chaos and excluding economic forcasts in the long run (Sect. 6.2).

Keywords

Phase Portrait Human Society Urban System Exogenous Shock Intentional Behavior 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. 6.1
    Ehrenberg, V.: Der Staat der Griechen. Zürich ( 1965 ); Meier, C.: Die Entstehung des Politischen bei den Griechen. Frankfurt (1983)Google Scholar
  2. 6.2
    Platonis Opera, 5 vols. Ed. J. Burnet. Oxford (1899–1906) (especially Politeia, Politikos); Cf. Cross, R.C./Woozley, A.D.: Plato’s Republic. A Philosophical Commentary. London (1964)Google Scholar
  3. 6.3
    Aristotle: Ethica Nicomachae, Politica (Oxford Classical Texts); Atheniesium Res Publica. Ed. F.G. Kenyon. Oxford (1920); Höffe, O.: Praktische Philosophie — Das Model des Aristoteles. München (1971); Barker, L.E.: The Political Thought of Plato and Aristotle. New York (1959)Google Scholar
  4. 6.4
    Hobbes, T.: The Elements of Law Natural and Politic (1640). Ed. F. Tönnies. London (1889); Leviathan, or the Matter, Form and Power of a Commonwealth, Ecclesiasticial and Civil (1651). Ed. C.B. Macpherson. Harmondsworth (1968); Gough, J.W.: The Social Contract. A Critical Study of its Development. Oxford (1957); Höffe, O. (ed.): Thomas Hobbes: Anthropologie und Staatsphilosophie. Freiburg (1981)Google Scholar
  5. 6.5
    Quesnay: Oeuvres économiques et philosophiques. Francfort (1988)Google Scholar
  6. 6.
    Figure 6.3a shows a “Tableau économique” from the “Elements de la philosophie rurale” (1767) of Marquis of Mirabeau; cf. Meek, R.L.: The interpretation of the “Tableau economique”, Economica 27 (1960) 322–347Google Scholar
  7. 6.7
    Serviere, G. de: Recueil d’ouvrages curieux de mathématique et de méchanique, ou description du cabinet de Monsieur Grollier de Serviere, avec des figures en taille-douce. Seconde édition. Lyon (1733) (Fig. 38); Rieter, H.: Quesnays Tableau Economique als Uhren-Analogie. In: Scherf, H. (ed.): Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie IX. Duncker and Humblot: Berlin (1990) 73Google Scholar
  8. 6.8
    Locke, J.: Two Treatises on Government (1689). Ed. P. Laslett. Cambridge (1970). Book II: Essay concerning the true original, and end of civil governmentGoogle Scholar
  9. 6.9
    Hume, D.: Essays and Treatise on Several Subjects. In two Volumes. I. Containing Essays, Moral, Political, and Literary. A New Edition. London (1784)Google Scholar
  10. 6.10
    Smith, A.: The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759). Ed. D.D. Raphael/A.L. Mac-fie. Oxford (1979)Google Scholar
  11. 6.11
    Cf. Skinner, A.S.: Adam Smith, science and the role of imagination. In: Todd, W.B. (ed.): Hume and the Enlightenment. Edinburgh University Press: Edinburgh (1974) 164–188Google Scholar
  12. 6.12
    Smith, A.: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Ed. E. Cannan. The University of Chicago Press: Chicago (1976) vol. 1, 478Google Scholar
  13. 6.
    Smith, A.: (see Note 12), vol. 1, 18Google Scholar
  14. 6.14
    Mayr, O.: Adam Smith und das Konzept der Regelung. In: Troitzsch/Wohlauf, G. (eds.): Technikgeschichte. Frankfurt (1980) 245Google Scholar
  15. 6.15
    Cf. Marchi, N.B. de: The empirical content and longevity of Ricardian economics. Economica 37 (1970) 258–259; Sowell, T.: Classical Economics Reconsidered. Princeton University Press: Princeton (1974) 118–120; Blaug, M.: The Methodology of Economics. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge (1980)Google Scholar
  16. 6.16
    Mill, J.S.: On the definition of political economy. In: Collected Works. Essays on Economy and Society. Ed. J.M. Robson. University of Toronto Press: Toronto (1967) vol. 4, 330; Hicks, J.: From classical to post-classical: The work of J.S. Mill. In: Hicks, J.: Classics and Moderns. Collected Essays on Economic Theory. Vol. III. Basil Blackwell: Oxford (1983) 60–70Google Scholar
  17. 6.17
    Georgescu-Roegen, N.: The Entropy Law and Economic Progress. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA (1971)Google Scholar
  18. 6.18
    Walras, L.: Principe d’une théorie mathématique de l’echange. Journal des Economistes 33 (1874) 1–21; Hicks, J.: Léon Walras. In: Hicks, J.: (see Note 16 ) 85–95Google Scholar
  19. 6.19
    Keynes, J.M.: The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. Vol. XIV. The General Theory and After. Ed. D. Moggridge. Macmillan: London (1973) 296Google Scholar
  20. 6.20
    Neumann, J. von/Morgenstern, O.: Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ (1943)Google Scholar
  21. 6.21
    Cf. Stegmüller, W: Probleme und Resultate der Wissenschaftstheorie und Analytischen Philosophie Bd. 1. Springer: Berlin (1969) 391Google Scholar
  22. 6.
    Cf. Shubik, M. (ed.): Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior. John Wiley: New York/London/Sidney (1964); Nash, J.F.: Equilibrium points in n-person games. Proceedings of National Academy of Science (USA) 36 (1950) 48–49Google Scholar
  23. 6.23
    For a survey compare Anderson, P.W./Arrow, K.J./Pines, D. (eds.): The Economy as an Evolving Complex System. Santa Fé Institute Studies in the Sciences of Complexity vol. 3. Addison-Wesley: Redwood City (1988); Barnett, W.A./Geweke, J./Shell, K. (eds.): Economic Complexity. Chaos, Sunspots, Bubbles, and Nonlinearity. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge (1989)Google Scholar
  24. 6.24
    Kalecki, M.: Theory of Economic Dynamics. Unwin University Books: London (1954); Samuelson, P.A.: Foundations of Economic Analysis. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA (1947)Google Scholar
  25. 6.25
    Goodwin, R.M.: Chaotic Economic Dynamics. Clarendon Press: Oxford (1990) 19CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. 6.26
    Rössler, O.E.: Chaos und Endophysik. In: Mainzer, K./Schirmacher, W. (eds.): Quanten, Chaos und Dämonen. Erkenntnistheoretische Aspekte der modernen Physik. B. I. Wissenschaftsverlag: Mannheim (1993)Google Scholar
  27. 6.
    Goodwin, R.M.: Chaotic Economic Dynamics (see Note 25) 113Google Scholar
  28. 6.28
    Lorenz, H.-W.: Nonlinear Dynamical Economics and Chaotic Motion. Springer: Berlin (1989); Goodwin, R.W.: A growth cycle. In: Hunt, E.K./Schwartz, J.G. (eds.): A Critique of Economic Theory. Penguin: Harmondsworth (1969) 442–449Google Scholar
  29. 6.29
    This idea stems back to Samuelson, P.A.: Generalized predator-prey oscillations in ecological and economic equilibrium. In: The Collected Scientific Papers of P.A. Samuelson. Ed. R.C. Merton. Vol III. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA (1972) 487–490Google Scholar
  30. 6.30
    Cf. Lorenz, H.-W: Nonlinear Dynamical Economics and Chaotic Motion. (See Note 27) 157; Goodwin, R.M.: Chaotic Economic Dynamics. (See Note 25 ) 117Google Scholar
  31. 6.31
    Cf. Farmer, J.D./Sidorowich, J.J.: Predicting Chaotic Time Series. Mineo: Los Alamos National Laboratory (1987)Google Scholar
  32. 6.
    In his “History of Economical Analysis”, J.A. Schumpeter had already discussed the possibility of multiple equilibrium points. But like Poincaré in the physical sciences, he was afraid of chaotic scenarios in economics: Schumpeter, J.A.: Geschichte der ökonomischen Analyse. Vandenhoeck and Ruprecht: Göttingen (1965)Google Scholar
  33. 6.33
    Arthur, W.B.: Positive feedbacks in the economy. Scientific American, February (1990) 92–99Google Scholar
  34. 6.34
    Arthur, W.B./Ermoliew, J.M./Kaniowski, J.M.: Path-dependent processes and the emergence of macro-structure. European Journal of Operational Research 30 (1987) 294–303; Helpman, E./Krugman, P.: Market Structure and Foreign Trade. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA (1985)Google Scholar
  35. 6.35
    Flood, R.L.: Complexity: A definition by construction of a conceptual framework. Systems Research 4(3) (1987) 177–185; Flood, R.L./Carson, E.R.: Dealing with Complexity. An Introduction to the Theory and Application of Systems Science. Plenum Press: New York (1988); An early inquiry of complexity in social sciences was written by Hayek, F.A. von: The Theory of Complex Phenomena. J.C.B. Mohr: Tübingen (1972)Google Scholar
  36. 6.36
    For a survey compare Cambel, A.B./Fritsch, B./Keller, J.U. (eds.): Dissipative Strukturen in integrierten Systemen. Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft: Baden-Baden (1989); Tainter, J.: The Collapse of Complex Societies. Cambridge University Press (1988); Dumouchel, P./Dupuy, J.-P. (eds.): L’Auto-Organisation de la Physique au Politique. Editions Du Seuil: Paris (1983)Google Scholar
  37. 6.37
    Malthus, T.R.: An Essay on the Principle of Population. London (1798)Google Scholar
  38. 6.38
    Spencer, H.: First Principles. D. Appleton and Co.: New York (1896) 527; Carneiro, R.L.: Structure, function, and equilibrium in the evolutionism of Herbert Spencer. Journal of Anthropological Research 29 (1973) 77–95Google Scholar
  39. 6.39
    For a review compare, for instance, Carneiro, R.L.: Successive reequilibrations as the mechanism of cultural evolution. In: Schieve, W.C./Allen, P.M. (eds.): Self-Organization and Dissipative Structures. Applications in the Physical and Social Sciences. University of Texas Press: Austin (1982) 110–115Google Scholar
  40. 6.40
    Allen, P.M.: Self-organization in the urban system. In: Schieve, W.C./Allen, P.M. (eds.): Self-Organization and Dissipative Structures. (See Note 39 ) 142–146Google Scholar
  41. 6.41
    Durkheim, E.: De la Division du Travail Social. Paris ( 1893 ); Les Règles de la Méthode Sociologique. Paris (1895)Google Scholar
  42. 6.42
    Weidlich, W: Das Modellierungskonzept der Synergetik für dynamisch sozioökonomische Prozesse. In: Mainzer, K./ Schirmacher, W. (eds.): Quanten, Chaos und Dämonen. (See Note 26) Figs. 6.12–16; Weidlich, W: Stability and cyclicity in social systems. In: Cambel, A.B. Fritsch, B./Keller, J.U. (eds.): Dissipative Strukturen in Integrierten Systemen. (See Note 36 ) 193–222Google Scholar
  43. 6.43
    For a survey compare Scott, W.R.: Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ (1992): Taylor, M.: The Possibility of Cooperation. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge (1987)Google Scholar
  44. 6.44
    Bott, E.: Urban families: Conjugal roles and social networks. Human Relations 8 (1955) 345–383; Knipscheer, C.P.M./Antonucci, T.C. (eds.): Social Network Research: Substantive Issues and Methodological Questions. Swets and Zeitlinger: Amsterdam (1990)Google Scholar
  45. 6.45
    Schelling. T.C.: Micromotives and Macrobehavior. W.W. Norton and Co.: New York (1978)Google Scholar
  46. 6.
    Glance, N.S./Huberman, B.A.; Organizational fluidity and sustainable cooperation, dynamics of computation group: Xerox Palo Alto Research Center: March 12 (1993) (Fig. 3)Google Scholar
  47. 6.
    See Note 46, Fig. 4 Google Scholar
  48. 6.48
    Dawkins, R.: The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press: New York (1976)Google Scholar
  49. 6.49
    Popper, K.R.: Evolutionary epistemology. In: Miller, D. (ed.): Popper Selections. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ (1985) 78–86Google Scholar
  50. 6.50
    Miller, M.S./Drexler, K.E.: Comparative ecology: A computational perspective. In: Huberman, B.A. (ed.): The Ecology of Computation. North-Holland: Amsterdam (1988) 51–76Google Scholar
  51. 6.51
    Compare Luhmann, N.: The self-reproduction of the law and its limits. In: Teubner, G. (ed.): Dilemmas of Law in the Welfare State. Berlin (1986) 111–127; Mayntz, R.: Differenzierung und Verselbständigung. Zur Entwicklung gesellschaftlicher Teilsysteme. Frankfurt (1988)Google Scholar
  52. 6.52
    Minsky, M.: The Society of Mind. Simon and Schuster: New York (1985) 314Google Scholar
  53. 6.
    Huberman, B.A. (ed.): The Ecology of Computation. (See Note 50) 81Google Scholar
  54. 6.54
    For a survey compare Kellermayr, K.H.: Lokale Computernetze LAN. Technologische Grundlagen, Architektur, Übersicht und Anwendungsbereiche. Springer: Wien (1986); Sharp, J.A.: Verteilte und parallele Computernetze. Architektur und Programmierung. VCH-Verlagsgesellschaft: Weinheim (1989); Barz, H.W.: Kommunikation und Computernetze. Konzepte, Protokolle und Standards. Carl Hanser: München (1991)Google Scholar
  55. 6.55
    Cerf, V.G.: Netztechnik, Spektrum der Wissenschaft Nov. 11 (1991) 76Google Scholar
  56. 6.
    Minsky, M.: The Society of Mind. (See Note 52)Google Scholar
  57. 6.57
    Hegel, G.W.F.: Phänomenologie des Geistes. (1807) In: Werke in zwanzig Bänden, vol. 3. Suhrkamp: Frankfurt (1972)Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1997

Authors and Affiliations

  • Klaus Mainzer
    • 1
  1. 1.Lehrstuhl für Philosophie und WissenschaftstheorieUniversität AugsburgAugsburgGermany

Personalised recommendations